Close to
two years back, on March 30 2002, the Industrial Credit and Investment
Corporation of India (ICICI) was through a reverse merger, integrated with
ICICI Bank. That was the beginning of a process that is leading to the
demise of development finance in the country. The reverse merger was the
result of a decision (announced
on October 25, 2001) by the ICICI to
transform itself into a universal bank that would engage itself not only
in traditional banking, but also investment banking and other financial
activities. The proposal also involved merging ICICI Personal Financial
Services Ltd and ICICI Capital Services Ltd with the bank, resulting in
the creation of a financial behemoth with assets of more than Rs. 95,000
crore. The new company was to become the first entity in India to serve as
a financial supermarket and offer almost every financial product under one
roof.
Since the announcement of
that decision, not only has the merger been put through, but similar moves
are underway to transform the other two principal development finance
institutions in the country, the Industrial Finance Corporation of India (IFCI),
established in 1948, and the Industrial Development Bank of India (IDBI),
created in 1964. In early February, Finance Minister Jaswant Singh
announced the government's decision to merge the IFCI with a big public
sector bank, like the Punjab National Bank. Following that decision, the
IFCI board has approved the proposal, rendering itself defunct.
It is expected that the decision would be implemented despite considerable
scepticism among both PNB shareholders and IFCI employees with regard to
the proposal. On his last day in office, the erstwhile Chairman and
Managing Director of IFCI, V. P. Singh, sought to assuage the fears of PNB
shareholders by saying that IFCI would clear most of its liabilities
before the merger. Freed of them, PNB, in his view, could leverage IFCI's
existing expertise on project financing, monitoring, advisory services and
term-lending to complement its existing business.
Finally,
recently the Parliament has approved the corporatisation of the IDBI,
which had been debated for more than a year, paving the way for its merger
with a bank as well. IDBI had earlier set up IDBI Bank as a subsidiary.
However, the process of restructuring IDBI has involved converting the
IDBI Bank into a stand alone bank, through the sale of IDBI's stake in the
institution. Since there is no clear declaration that IDBI Bank would be
chosen as the partner bank for the proposed merger of the DFI, talk of an
alternative is very much in the air. Among the banks being mentioned are:
Bank of Baroda, Punjab National Bank, Indian Bank and Canara Bank.
When the
bill to corporatise IDBI was put through with some difficulty in the Rajya
Sabha, it appeared that the government had provided two commitments. The
first was that the government would retain a majority stake in the entity
into which the IDBI would be transformed.
The government currently
has a 58.47 per cent stake in IDBI.
And, second that the
development finance emphasis of the institution would be retained. But
already doubts are being expressed about the government's willingness to
stick to the first of these commitments. And once the merger creates a
universal bank as a new entity, with multiple interests and a strong
emphasis on commercial profits, it is unclear how the second commitment
can be met either.
As part of
the corporatisation process, the
IDBI has received a forbearance of five
years with respect to the SLR requirement. It is however ready to meet the
obligation of cash reserve ratio (CRR) of around Rs 2,000 crore to the RBI
immediately. The SLR requirement for the institution is pegged at around
Rs 18,000 crore. The non-performing assets (NPAs) of around Rs 15,000
crore are likely to be transferred out of the institution as and when the
merger with a bank takes place.
These developments on the development banking front do herald a new era.
An important financial intervention adopted by almost all
late-industrialising developing countries, besides pre-emption of bank
credit for specific purposes, was the creation of special development
banks with the mandate to provide adequate, even subsidised, credit to
selected industrial establishments and the agricultural sector. According
to an OECD estimate quoted by Eshag, there were about 340 such banks
operating in some 80 developing countries in the mid-1960s. Over half
these banks were state-owned and funded by the exchequer, the remainder
had a mixed ownership or were private. Mixed and private banks were given
government subsidies to enable them to earn a normal rate of profit.
The principal motivation for
the creation of such financial institutions was to make up for the failure
of private financial agents to provide certain kinds of credit to certain
kinds of clients. Private institutions may fail to do so because of high
default risks that cannot be covered by high enough risk premiums because
such rates are not viable. In other instances, failure may be because of
the unwillingness of financial agents to take on certain kinds of risk, or
because anticipated returns to private agents are much lower than the
social returns in the investment concerned.
In practice, financial intermediaries seek
to tailor the demands for credit from them with their funds by adjusting
not just interest rates, but also the terms on which credit is provided.
Lending gets linked to collateral, and the nature and quality of that
collateral is adjusted according to the nature of the borrower and supply
and demand conditions in the credit market. In the event, depending on the
quantum and costs of funds available to the financial intermediary, the
market tends to ration out borrowers to differing extents. In such
circumstances, borrowers are rationed out because they are considered
risky, but they may not be the ones that are the least important from a
social point of view.
These problems can be
aggravated because certain kinds of insurance markets for dealing with
risk are absent and because in some (especially, developing-country)
contexts, certain kinds of long-term contracts may not just exist. They
need to be created by the state, and till such time state-backed lending
would be needed to fill the gap.
Industrial development banks also help deal
with the fact that local industrialists may not have adequate capital to
invest in capacity of the requisite scale in more capital-intensive
industries characterised by significant economies of scale. They help
promote such ventures through their lending and investment practices and
often provide technical assistance to their clients. Some development
banks are expected to focus on the small scale industrial sector,
providing them with long-term finance and working capital at subsidised
interest rates and longer grace periods, as well as offering training and
technical assistance in areas like marketing.
Fundamentally of course, development banking is required because social
returns exceed private returns. This problem arises because private
lenders are concerned only with the return they receive. On the other
hand,
the total return to a project includes the
additional surplus (or profit) accruing to the entrepreneur. The projects
that offer the best return to the lender may not be those with the highest
total expected return. As a result, good projects get rationed out,
necessitating measures such as development banking or directed credit.
Finally, directed credit has positive
fiscal consequences. In contrast to subsidies, such credit reduces the
demand placed on the government's own revenues. This makes directed credit
an advantageous option in developing countries faced with chronic
budgetary difficulties that limit their ability to use budgetary subsidies
to achieve a certain allocation of investible resources.
It must be said that
development banks have played an important role in the Indian context. In
his deposition before the Parliamentary Standing Committee on Finance
(1999-2000) on 18 September 2000, the Managing Director of ICICI stated:
"disbursement by FIs constituted around fifty per cent of gross fixed
capital formation by the private corporate sector in the pre-liberalised
era. If you see the financial institutions' disbursement versus bank
credit to industry right from 1951 to the last year, we see that financial
institutions have provided significantly more credit for the creation of
capital in industry in India. It has grown year after year … Thus, the FIs
have played a pivotal role in the development of Indian industry and
have fulfilled their initial objective i.e. to spur industrialisation in
the country over the last three to four decades."
The corporatisation, transformation into universal banks and subsequent
privatisation of the DFIs is bound to undermine this role of theirs. The
justification for the conversion to universal banking as provided by the
Industrial Investment Bank of India (IIBI) in a written reply to the
Parliamentary Standing Committee indicates this: "Since
compartmentalisation of activities leads to greater transactions cost and
inefficiency, no financial intermediary can survive competition if it does
not allow itself flexibility to change. In the new financial environment, IIBI is of the opinion that a financial player may be either placed
naturally for resources like a commercial bank, or may be a pure financial
service provider and retailer like the NBFCs. Still another option is to
build a financial supermarket where all the services are available under
a single umbrella. The advantages are that they would be free to choose
the product mix of their operations and configure activities for optimum
allocation of their resources."
The CEO of ICICI made clear what this means in terms of emphasis: "When we
were set up, our role was to meet long term resource requirements of the
industry. With liberalisation, the role has slightly changed. It became
developing India's debt market, financing India's infrastructure
development, etc. With globalisation, I think, the role is set to change
further. Now we have to stress on profitability, shareholder value,
corporate governance, while at the same time not losing sight of our goals
– the goals that were originally set for us – and the goals that were set
up in the interim with liberalisation." Unfortunately, the emphasis on
those goals would remain only with regulation. But regulation is diluted
by liberalisation.
There is
another way in which the gradual dissolution of the core of India's
development banking infrastructure is related to the process of
liberalisation. This is through the effects of liberalisation on the
profitability of an institution like the IFCI, for example. According to
the
D. Basu Expert Committee, which was appointed by IFCI's governing board
immediately following its corporatisation and initial public offering in
1993, to examine the causes of the large NPAs accumulated by the
institution and suggest a restructuring, IFCI embarked upon a programme of
rapid expansion of business. To scale up the volume of business, it
increasingly raised resources from the debt markets. This was at a time
when interest rates were relatively high. In order to cover the high cost
borrowings, the institution was forced to make investments in what were
considered high yielding loan assets.
Unfortunately, this occurred
at a time when financial liberalisation had put an end to the traditional
consortium mode of lending, in which all major financial institutions
collaborated in lending to a single borrower as per a mutually agreed
pattern of sharing. Liberalisation was introducing an element of
competition among financial institutions. In the event, in search of high
returns IFCI chose to take relatively large exposures in several
greenfield projects (notably in the steel and oil sectors).
For a number of reasons, these projects did not deliver on their promise.
Many of these projects had expected to raise substantial equity from the
capital market as well as from the internal resources of group companies.
Depressed conditions in the capital market put paid to the first.
Recessionary conditions limited the second. Many of these groups were in
the traditional commodity sectors such as iron and steel, textiles,
synthetic fibres, cement, sugar, basic chemicals, synthetic resins,
plastics, etc. Besides the general recessionary environment, some of these
sectors were particularly affected by the abolition of import controls and
the gradual reduction of tariffs. Internal resource generation, therefore,
fell short of expectations. As a result, with inadequate own-financing in
the pipeline, many of these projects suffered from cost- and
time-overruns.
Unlike other financial institutions, IFCI had not diversified into other
types of businesses. Project finance still accounted for 94 per cent of
IFCI's business assets. As a result, the impact of NPAs arising from the
factors cited above was greater in the case of IFCI than in the case of
other institutions. In addition, there was sharp rise in IFCI's gross NPA
level in 1998-99 (Rs. 5,783.56 crore as against Rs. 4,159.84 crore in the
previous year), as a result of the implementation of the mandatory RBI
guidelines for classifying non-performing assets. As a result, certain
loans, particularly those relating to projects under implementation, which
had been treated as performing assets in earlier years, had to be
classified as non-performing.
The Basu Committee had noted that some of the factors referred to above
such as impact of trade policy liberalisation and tariff reduction,
recessionary conditions in the late 1990s, depressed conditions in the
capital market, etc., affected other DFIs and banks as well. However, the
impact was particularly pronounced in the case of IFCI, as the
concentration of risk relative to net worth was much higher. Also, as
already stated, other DFIs had started diversifying into non-project
related lending business. It was difficult to survive as a development
finance institution in the new environment.
Thus, the decline of development finance is clearly related to the process
of economic liberalisation. However, as a number of industry associations
have noted in recent times, it hardly is true that in a time of growing
competition for Indian firms from international business and a growing
liberalisation-induced shift in the investment and lending practices of
banks and NBFCs away from manufacturing, state support for domestic
private investment is not insignificant.
The view that development finance does not matter is countered by the fact
that thus far, right through the years of liberalisation, the state has
been forced to maintain a high ratio of disbursement of financial
institutions to Gross Domestic Capital Formation in the private corporate
sector (Chart 1). That ratio has risen sharply in recent times. However,
the argument that development finance is irrelevant is backed up by
evidence that in the case of many new projects, the share of equity
finance in total resources is quite high (Chart 2). The stock market is
replacing the DFIs, it is claimed. But such evidence is based on
information collected by the Department of Company Affairs from firms that
have issued prospectuses. That is, they are firms that have the ability to
and have chosen to tap capital markets and have hence issued prospectuses.
But, it is not clear whether these firms actually managed to raise the
requisite capital from equity markets. And though the number of such
projects is growing, it still remains small (Chart 3). Further, the number
of such projects is quite volatile. Thus, relying on these figures to
justify undermining a framework that has served Indian industry well is
completely unwarranted. But, the reasons why these arguments are purveyed
is that they serve as the basis for justifying the government's decision
to adopt large-scale financial liberalisation in its bid to attract and
appease international financial capital. In that framework of policy,
support for building a domestic manufacturing base obviously does not make
sense.