In an implicit defence of the Budget proposals for
2002-03, Revenue Secretary S. Narayan attacked the corporate sector for
failing to deliver. Speaking to representatives of the Confederation of
Indian Industry during a post-Budget interaction, he argued that unlike
last year when the budget provided Rs. 16,000 crore in the form of
“giveaways”, this year’s budget offers none, because of the lack of
resources resulting from the poor performance of industry. Industry’s
failure to deliver, according to him, had in fact forced the government to
impose additional taxes on the middle classes. “The corporate world must
understand that this year the middle class is bearing your burden,” he is
reported to have said.
This candid assessment of differential contributions made and burdens
borne by different sections is likely to have been inspired in the main by
two factors. First, it was possibly triggered by disappointment with the
adverse response of industry and finance in and through the media. That
response would only serve to strengthen resentment among sections
adversely affected by the surcharge on income taxes, reduced tax
concessions for savings, higher LPG and kerosene prices, hiked sugar
prices, enhanced postal and rail tariffs and increased excise duties on
items of mass consumption. Through these means the Finance Minister has
after all mobilised a significant amount of resources over a full year.
Second, the response was possibly driven by the government’s own shock
with the shortfall in revenues in 2001-02 relative to what was budgeted
for. As Chart 1, shows the shortfall in gross tax revenue in 2001-02
relative to what was budgeted for amounted to a whopping 30,000 crore or
13 per cent of the budgeted figure. The shortfall occurred in all major
taxes (corporation and income taxes and customs and excise duties).
However, there were significant differences in the extent of the
shortfall, which amounted to 9 per cent in the case of excise, 12 per cent
in the case of income tax, 15 per cent in the case of corporation tax and
a huge 21 per cent in the case of customs tariffs. As a result of the last
of these, customs duties collected in 2001-02 were 9 per cent less than
actual collections in 2001-02.
The shortfall in revenues has meant that the post-liberalisation trend of
a decline and subsequent stagnation of the tax-GDP ratio has persisted
(Chart 5). Combined with the government’s obsession to keep the deficit
under control, irrespective of the supply situation in the economy, and
despite the government’s accelerated effort to garner resources from
disinvestments, this has substantially reduced its ability to stimulate
the economy. In year’s of recession this contributes to a worsening of the
fiscal position of the government.
In fact, the differentials in the extent of the revenue shortfall in the
case of different taxes do suggest that the shortfalls in revenue
generation in 2001-02 occurred because of a combination of reduced tax
rates and the industrial recession. It is known that over the
liberalization years the area in which the most substantial reductions
have been made in taxes is customs duties. It was presumed that these
reductions would be accompanied by a burgeoning of trade, resulting in
increased rather than decreased customs revenues. The huge shortfall in
customs duty collections reflect the fact that the expectation that duty
reduction would be accompanied by an increase in trade volumes has been
belied. If in addition trade growth tends to slow for external reasons,
tax collections collapse, as happened in 2001-02.
This experience with the effects of tax reduction and rationalisation on
revenue generation has implications for other areas of taxes as well.
Though in these cases revised revenue estimates for 2001-02 are higher
than in 2000-01, the shortfall relative to budgeted estimates must to some
degree be attributed to the reduction in rates and the rationalisation of
tariffs. Thus, if the trend towards revenue shortfall in 2001-02 is to be
stalled, it would be necessary for the government to both adjust tax rates
or the tax base suitably as well as work towards a reversal of the
recession.
Interestingly, however, the shortfall in tax collection has not affected
the government’s expenditure as adversely as is to be expected. As Chart 3
shows, while there was a shortfall in revenue expenditures relative to
budget estimates to the tune of Rs. 10,000 crore, an increase in plan
expenditure relative to budgeted, has resulted in an overall shortfall in
expenditure of just about Rs. 5000 crore. The question then is how the
government has been able to sustain its expenditures despite the huge tax
collection shortfall.
There are two developments of relevance here, besides the fact that a
third of the tax revenue shortfall is a burden on the states rather than
the centre, making the latter’s revenue loss on this count about Rs.
20,000 crore. First, despite the recession, the government has been able
not just to meet but in fact exceed its non-tax revenue by Rs.1,500 crore
relative to what was budgeted (Chart 4). This is predominantly due to
windfall gains in two areas. An excess accretion of Rs. 3,000 crore in the
case of Dividends and Profits, due to a sharp jump in dividends from
public sector enterprises from the budgeted Rs.5419.50 crore to the
realised Rs.10295.78 crore. This is largely explained by the one-time
“revenue farming” resorted to by the government, by transferring to itself
cash surpluses with enterprises like VSNL prior to their disinvestment.
The other was the gain in non-tax revenues in Communications, which stood
at Rs.7395.21 crore against a budgeted figure of Rs.3725.29 crore because
of licence fees for basic/cellular telecom services and fees from VSNL,
MTNL and BSNL.
The second, and more obvious way in which the government has been able to
keep expenditures going is by increasing its budgeted fiscal deficit of Rs.
116314 crore to an estimated Rs.131721 crore and its budgeted open market
borrowing of Rs. 77353 crore to an actual Rs. 91480 crore, which helped
neutralise the much lower than budgeted receipts from disinvestments as
well.
It should be obvious that the government cannot expect the first of these
windfall gains to accrue every year. Yet, the budgeted figures for 2002-03
provides for a large contribution from non-tax revenues, that rose in
2001-02 to 33 per cent of all revenues as compared with 28.9 per cent in
2000-01. Revenues from Dividends and Profits are expected to remain at Rs.
18805 crore as compared with Rs. 18292 crore and revenues from the
Communications sector at Rs.5256 crore as compare with Rs. 7395 crore. But
with the government having chosen to budget for a fiscal deficit of just
Rs.135524 crore in 2002-03 as compared with 131721 crore in 2001-02, even
this is inadequate to finance the close to Rs.46,000 crore increase in
expenditure it expects to incur in the coming financial year (Chart 3).
It is for this reason that the government has decided to resort to a range
of imposts which put together seems to have no driving perspective other
than increasing revenues through any means possible. In the event, the
government has budgeted for a Rs.39107 crore increase in tax revenues
(Chart 2). Since revenues from Customs duties are expected to rise by just
Rs. 2000 crore from their depressed 2001-02 levels, the burden must be
imposed through other means. The structure of that burden is disconcerting
indeed. While corporation taxes are expected to contribute an additional
Rs.9,500 crore, taxes on income are budgeted to garner an additional
Rs.8,000 crore and excise duties a huge Rs.17,000 crore.
Since the corporate tax rate on foreign companies has been reduced from 48
to 40 per cent, all of the increase here is due to the hike in surcharge
and the expected buoyancy. The gains in income taxation are expected to
come from a combination of buoyancy, changes in the dividend tax, the
effects of the surcharge and a reduction in tax exemptions for savings by
middle class households. And the increase in excise duties, which would
now apply at higher rates on goods that were taxed at a lower 4 per cent,
would be a burden on all consumers, rich and poor alike. This change in
the structure of taxation is clearly regressive. The Revenue Secretary is
wrong to say the burden would be borne by the middle class. It would fall
heavily on the poor as well.
The problem is that this burden is unlikely to resolve the problem of
revenue shortfall that the government confronted in 2001-02. The budget
presumes that nominal incomes in 2002-03 would grow at the rate of 10.7
per cent in 2002-03 as compared with 10.9 per cent in 2001-02. The
government expected to mobilise an additional Rs.38,000 crore by way of
tax revenues in 2001-02 but actually garnered only an additional Rs.8,000
crore. Yet this time around, with nominal GDP growth expected to be even
lower, it has budgeted for an increase in revenues of Rs.39,107 crore. It
clearly expects the new taxes to do the job.
However, the slump in revenues last year was not just the effect of
accumulated giveaways, it was also the result of the slump in demand and
growth. The government spent an additional Rs.38825 crore last year, but
could not correct for that slump. Even with its heroic assumptions
regarding non-tax revenues it expects to spend an additional Rs. 45873
crore in 2002-03. After allowing for inflation, this is a small increase.
Clearly that cannot achieve what last year’s effort did not. It is no
surprise therefore that the Revenue Secretary is exhorting the private
sector to “deliver”, ignoring the fact that the latter is waiting for the
government to stimulate growth.
It is here that the fact that the government has missed an opportunity in
2001-02, and threatens to do so in 2002-03 as well, is of relevance.
Budget 2002-03 exposes the complete paralysis in economic policy-making
that characterises the BJP-led government. That paralysis stems from two
sources, which together have trapped the government in a crisis of its own
making. The first of these is the collapse in the revenue-generating
capacity of the Central government discussed above. The second, is the
persistence of a high interest burden resulting from the decision taken as
part of economic reform to borrow from the open market at higher rates of
interest than charged by the Reserve Bank of India. When combined with the
goal of limiting the fiscal deficit, these trends have resulted in a loss
in its room for manoeuvre. This has meant that despite the steep recession
in the industrial sector, evidence of the persistence of a high incidence
of poverty and the rising levels of unemployment and under-employment, the
government has not been able to provide any thrust in the budget for
restoration of growth and improvement in the welfare of the common people.
This paralysis is indeed shocking because economic circumstances are such
that they provide the government with a major opportunity. Food stocks
touched record levels of more than 60 million tonnes, foreign exchange
reserves are comfortable and inflation rules at an all time low. These
circumstances demand that the government should use the food stocks it has
at hand to launch a massive food-for-work programme aimed at strengthening
rural and urban infrastructure, with the complementary rupee resources
required financed with an expanded deficit. This, given the easy supply
situation would not result in inflation, but in an expansion of output and
employment and a concomitant reduction in rural and urban poverty.
Further, in as much as the recession is partly responsible for the
collapse in revenue generation, as the Finance Minister himself admits,
the recovery in growth would lead to an increase in revenues that would
help sustain the investment thrust.
Despite protestations to the contrary, effort along the food-for-work
front has been meagre. As Chart 7 shows, the expenditure on rural
employment was raised by Rs.1300 crore in 2001-02, by introducing a food
component of just Rs.800 crore. And the budget figures for 2002-03 expect
to raise these expenditures by just Rs. 371 crore, though the food
component is raised by Rs. 421 crore. That this is a minimal use of the
foodstock should be clear from the fact that stocks with the government
are valued in excess of Rs.50,000 crore.
The point is that the cost of carrying these stocks has increased the
subsidy bill of the government substantially, from Rs.12125 crore in
2000-01 to Rs.17,612 crore in 2001-02 and a budgeted Rs. 21,200 crore in
2002-03 (Chart 6). The government could have saved much on these subsidies
by diverting stocks to a food-for-work programme, which would have helped
build rural infrastructure and spur growth.
But paralysed by its internalisation of the obsession with the size of the
fiscal deficit, the BJP-led government has not merely chosen to forsake
this opportunity, but to use the large foodstocks to launch an attach on
the farming community. There are two ways in which the government has
decided to rid itself of the food stocks that provide the above
opportunity: first, it is choosing to dispose as much of these stocks. The
Finance Minister has listed a number mechanisms through which he plans to
reduce the level of stockholding. These include increased allocations for
BPL families; launching of a major food for work programme; allocation of
30 lakh tonnes of free foodgrain to the states for relief works in areas
affected by natural calamities; open market sales of 30 lakh tonnes; and
enhanced incentives for export of foodgrains.
Of these the budgeted allocation of food for employment programmes in
2002-03 totals Rs. 1221 crore as compared with Rs. 800 crore in 2001-02,
indicating the rather limited increase on this ground. The real effort at
disposal is likely to occur through provision to the trade at extremely
low prices for sale either in the domestic or export market.
The second, medium and long term strategy for reducing the embarrassing
level of foodstocks is to curtail the level of procurement. The Finance
Minister has declared that: “The current situation of open-ended
procurement by FCI at a high price and disposable at a heavily subsidised
price is not sustainable.” This is nothing but a misleading justification
of a decision to dismantle the system of procurement and distribution. The
reason why stocks with the government are high as they are is its decision
in recent times to repeatedly increase the issue price of foodgrains,
which resulted in a fall in offtake. This not only increased stocks with
the government but also resulted in large outlay on “subsidies” aimed at
covering the carrying costs of the FCI.
In response to that problem the government is seeking to limit its
procurement so as to reduce the accretion to its stocks. This would leave
farmers to their own resources and expose the farming community to
fluctuations in market prices at a time when international prices of
agricultural commodities are falling. The impact of the latter is
intensified by the removal of quantitative restrictions and the Centre’s
hesitation to raise tariffs on agricultural imports substantially, though
the evidence of protection for agriculture in the G-7 is overwhelming.
Further, at a time when competition from exports from abroad is
intensifying, the ability of domestic producers to face up to
international competition is being undermined by the decision to cut
fertiliser subsidies which would raise fertiliser prices by at least 5 per
cent.
Thus it is
not just that the budget misses a major opportunity to spur growth in a
slowing economy, but it imposes or seeks to impose new burdens on those
most effected by the global and domestic slowdown. One are where this can
have extremely debilitating consequences is in the evolving fiscal
relationship between the Centre and the states. The budget threatens to
accelerate the slowdown in the economy by increasing the fiscal squeeze
applied on the states. Out of the Rs.30,000 crore shortfall in tax
revenues as a result of the Centre’s fiscal reform, close to Rs. 10,000
crore would have accrued to state governments as their share of devolved
taxes. This loss would only intensify the fiscal crunch that the states
have been facing. In addition, the government has decided to use these
financial difficulties of the states to force them to adopt World Bank and
IMF type reform. Thus as much as Rs. 12,300 crore is being provided as
“reform-linked assistance” to states and another Rs.2,500 crore for policy
reforms in sectors which are constraining growth and development. This
totals close to Rs. 15,000 crore or as much as a third of the budgeted
central plan assistance to the state governments of Rs.46,629 crore for
2002-03. Thus a major chunk of statutory central transfers are now being
linked to the willingness of the states to implement neoliberal reform.
After putting the states in a fiscal bind through its own policies, the
BJP government is now using what are constitutionally warranted transfers
to impose its own failed economic ideology on the state governments. This
effort to impose deflationary and contractionary policies that are
generating a crisis at the central level on state governments as well is a
sure means of widening and
intensifying the crisis
facing the economy today.