The
crippling role of the debt burden in affecting the finances of state
governments in India has been noted in the previous issue of MacroScan.
The Twelfth Finance Commission (hereafter TFC) specifically addressed
this issue, as one of its terms of reference specified that ''the
Commission may, after making as assessment of the debt position
of the States as on 31 March 2004, suggest such corrective measures
as are deemed necessary, consistent with macroeconomic stability
and debt sustainability.''
The
high interest payment obligations of States is one of the principal
reasons for the tremendous pressure on their finances. Some attempt
to reduce this pressure has been made since September 2002 under
the debt-swap scheme of the Central Government, under which ''high-cost
debt'' (i.e. carrying an interest rate of 13 per cent or above)
on state plans or small savings could be exchanged for market borrowings
and small savings securities, which at that point carried interest
of around 7 per cent.
Until March 2005, around Rs. 103,000 crore of state government debt
was swapped under this scheme. This reduced the average interest
rate paid by States to some extent, and also changed the composition
and maturity profile of the debt, but not the overall stock of the
debt. However, the rather limited nature of the swap has limited
the beneficial effects for the States.
The
TFC has introduced a package for debt reduction with two main components.
The first is the consolidation of all State debt outstanding to
the Centre on 31 March 2004, at an interest rate of 7 per cent to
be repaid over 20 years. The second, and much more problematic,
proposal is a new debt relief scheme linked to the reduction in
the revenue deficits of States.
Under this scheme, the repayments due on Central loans from the
current year to 2009-10 (after consolidation) will be eligible for
write-off, but the amount of write-off of repayment will be linked
to the abolsute amount by which the revenue deficit is reduced in
each successive year over the entire period. A pre-condition for
eligibility to this scheme is the enactment of fiscal responsibility
legislation: thus the scheme will be available to States only from
the year they ''qualify'' by bringing in such a law. In turn, States
would increasingly seek market borrowing or borrowing from other
sources than the Centre, in line with another recommendation of
the TFC, that the Centre stop acting as an intermediary for debt
taken on by the States.
Table
1: Debt profile of states in 2002-03 |
State |
Debt
to GSDP ratio
(per cent)
|
Share
in total debt of states
(per cent)
|
Range
of ratio of interest
payments to revenue receipts
(per cent)
|
General
category states |
Andhra Pradesh |
28.85 |
7.5 |
22-28 |
Bihar |
55.33 |
4.79 |
22-28 |
Chhattisgarh |
25.46 |
1.2 |
10-18 |
Goa |
28.15 |
0.45 |
18-22 |
Gujarat |
33.93 |
6.61 |
22-28 |
Haryana |
27.85 |
2.7 |
22-28 |
Jharkhand |
24.28 |
1.29 |
18-22 |
Karnataka |
25.12 |
4.72 |
18-22 |
Kerala |
36.34 |
4.65 |
22-28 |
Madhya Pradesh |
32.28 |
4.07 |
18-22 |
Maharashtra |
21.56 |
9.51 |
18-22 |
Orissa |
62.93 |
4.23 |
›
35 |
Punjab |
48.51 |
5.52 |
›
35 |
Rajasthan |
45.38 |
6.31 |
28-35 |
Tamil Nadu |
26.8 |
6.02 |
18-22 |
Uttar Pradesh |
39.08 |
11.9 |
28-35 |
West Bengal |
41.15 |
10.46 |
›
35 |
Special category states |
Arunachal Pradesh |
55.45 |
0.18 |
10-18 |
Assam |
33.91 |
1.94 |
10-18 |
Himachal Pradesh |
63.25 |
1.71 |
28-35 |
Jammu & Kashmir |
53.8 |
1.65 |
10-18 |
Manipur |
43.08 |
0.31 |
10-18 |
Meghalaya |
32.17 |
0.22 |
10-18 |
Mizoram |
81.56 |
0.27 |
10-18 |
Nagaland |
52.1 |
0.38 |
10-18 |
Sikkim |
60.27 |
0.13 |
10-18 |
Tripura |
37.78 |
0.46 |
10-18 |
Uttaranchal |
32.37 |
0.8 |
10-18 |
The
rationale for these oppressive conditions is stated as follows:
''As the states are increasingly exposed to the markets for borrowing,
their fiscal position would be increasingly assessed by the markets.
They may be forced to pay higher than average interst rates to cover
additional risk if the publci finances are not evaluated to be robust
by the assessment of the market. We are relying therefore on two
mechanisms for fiscal correction: self-evaluation under the Fiscal
Responsibility Act and exposure to the market.'' (page 84)
It is evident from Chart 1 that the role of the Centre as creditor
to the States has already declined quite sharply over the past five
years, and the value of the central loand outstanding has fallen
both in nominal value terms and as a share of the total outstanding
debt of the States. This has not meant that the debt burden of States
has ben very much reduced – Table 1 indicates that a significant
number of states still have debt-GSDP ratios of more than 40 per
cent and interest payments amounting to more than 28 per cent of
revenue receipts.
Not context with requiring that states enact fiscal responsibility
legislation as a precondition for availing of debt relief, the TFC
has also specified what such legislation should provide for ''at
a minimum''! This includes the following features:
-
eliminating the revenue deficit by 2008-09
-
reducing the fiscal deficit to 3 per cent of GSDP or its equivalent
defined as a ratio of interest payments to revenue receipts
-
bringing out annual reduction targets of revenue and fiscal deficits.
In
addition, the TFC states that ''States should follow a recruitment
and wage policy, in a manner such that the total salary bill relative
to revenue expenditure net of interest payments and pensions does
not exceed 35 per cent.'' The TFC even demands withdrawal of reduction
of the public sector: ''In the period of restructuring, that is
2005-10, state governments should draw up a programme that includes
closure of almost all loss making SLPEs (state level public enterprises).''
The problematic theoretical framework and lack of recognition of
socio-economic reality that are embedded in these conditions are
truly disturbing. The macroeconomic problems with a rigid fiscal
responsibility framework that specifies what are finally only arbitrary
limits to revenue and fiscal deficits are now well know across the
world and are even becoming evident in India within the first year
of such legislation been enacted.
These rigid numerical constraints are not just awkward an unnecessary
but also pro-cyclical, since they operate to intensify and prolong
slumps and even convert them into depressions. They are also foolish,
since they can prevent important and socially necessary public expenditure
which is required to improve current welfare and future growth prospects.
There is no reason to keep capital expenditure within some predetermined
numerical limit, since even debt sustainability depends upon the
relation between the interest rate and anticipated return from public
investment. So restricting capital account deficits to 3 per cent
of GSDP makes little sense.
In addition there is the issue of social returns, which appear to
be completely ignored by the TFC. In requiring the States to keep
the salary bill within a prespecified limit, and demanding the closure
of loss-making public enterprises, the TFC is ignoring the social
role that can be played by public employees and even loss-making
public enterprises that fulfill some social functions.
Let us consider what precisely such conditions will entail for the
state governments. Remember also that the revenue raising capacity
of the States is limited, more so since the Centre has taken upn
itself all power to tax service sector incomes. If revenue deficits
are to be progressively reduced and broguht down to zero, this necessarily
means that revenue expenditures wil have to be cut. In most states,
by far the largest item of expenditure on the revenue account is
in fact that for salaries. It is completely wrong to see these as
unnecessary or unproductive expenditures, since these are for who
are to provide the important public services that everyone acknowledges
to be essential. Since state governments are responsible for almost
all of the expenditures that affect the quality of life of ordinary
citizens on the ground, from infrastructure and sanitation to health
and education, preventing expenditure on wages and salaries for
those who would perform these functions is bizarre in the extreme.
The role of the Finance Commission, as envisaged by the Constitution,
is to deal with and prevent state governments from running up large
revenue deficits, by ensuring a distribution of fiscal resources
between Centre and States that would allow the States to fulfill
their social and constitutional responsibilities within their means.
However, successive Finance Commission have failed to achieve this.
And a substantial part of the problem is that the Cnetre itself
has failed on the revenue mobilisation front, especially since the
early 1990s, such that central transfers to the States have been
falling as a share of GDP.
In this context, instead of confronting this problem and addressing
the central issues of inadequate revenue generation by the Centre
and its adverse implications for state finances, what the TFC has
done is effectively to sound the death knell of fiscal federalism.
State governments are to be forced into the same neoliberal economic
policy straitjacket that the Centre has chosen to function within.
They are to be prevented from exercising their own options with
respect to how much revenue and capital spending they can undertake;
they are to be limited in terms of how many people they can employ
and how much they can be paid; they are to close down loss-making
state-owned enterprises even if these are contributing to the public
good; they are to be forced to turn directly to unintermediated
market borrowing or accessing loans from mutlilateral insitutions
that also carry similar conditionalities, and so on.
All in all, this amounts to a direct attack on the fiscal autonomy
of states, and therefore in effect a betrayal of the spirit of the
Constitution, which recognises the possibility of different economic
approaches by different state governments.
It is ironic – but also alarming – that the social and political
fallout of such apparently ''technocratic'' decisions is not recognised.
Depriving people of necessary public services and reducing the possibilities
of sustained development are not only likely to make those at the
helm of particular state governments unpopular. They are also likely
to increase disaffection with the entire national supposedly federalist
system and thereby encourage extremely dangerous separatist tendencies.
The evident reaction of people in many parts of the European Union
to a similar project should provide a telling example. The ''Growth
and Stability Pact'' which specified similarly foolish fiscal constraints
upon EU member governments has created higher unemployment and levels
of economic activity well below potential, and has led to a popular
backlash which is increasingly questioning the entire project.
The reason is that the policies – and even the proposed Constitution
- were seen as driven by corporate interests and operating against
the interest of people and the broader social good, which cannot
be calculated in terms of market principles. Policy makers in India
should take note: there is no reason why such policies should not
lead to similar backlash in our own federal structure.
|