The
dramatic expansion of India's Information technology (IT) sector
during the 1990s, albeit from a low base, is widely seen as heralding
India's emergence as a global IT and software powerhouse. This
'popular' perception has underlying it a less pervasive
but more sophisticated argument. According to that argument, there
are certain defining features of the information technology industry
which provide a new digital opportunity to countries with the requisite
knowledge- and skill-base and with the appropriate policy regime.
And as nations like India exploit that digital opportunity, it is
expected, that the wide, persisting and even growing technology, productivity
and income gaps between the developed and developing countries would
shrink, creating a whole new international economic order.
The
new optimism generated by the IT 'revolution' stems in part
from the rapid proliferation of an almost borderless industry. The
two main sources of information on the IT sector in India are IDC
(India) and the National Association of Software and Service Companies
(NASSCOM). According to IDC (India), the annual rate of growth of
IT spending in India was well above 20 per cent in most years during
the 1990s, with growth peaking at a remarkable 59 per cent in 1994-95.
NASSCOM's figures too reflect a rapid growth of the IT market
in India from Rs. 32.3 billion in 1993-94 to Rs. 135.7 billion in
1998-99 (Chart 1). The turnover of the IT industry was, however, much
larger than this, given the rapid increase in software exports. Software
exports have risen at a remarkable rate, from an estimated $150 million
at the beginning of the decade to close to $4 billion in 1999-00.
According to NASSCOM, software exports rose by 57 per cent in 1999-00.
The
current size of the domestic IT industry can be gleaned by combining
figures from IDC and NASSCOM. Domestic IT spending is estimated at
Rs. 16,538 crore in 1999-00 by IDC. Add to this NASSCOM's estimate
of software exports to the tune of Rs. 17,150 crore in that year,
and we are speaking of an industry with a turnover of around Rs. 35,000
crore a year. NASSCOM estimates that the IT industry grew from about
Rs. 6345 crore ($2.04 billion) in 1994-95 to Rs.24,781 crore ($6.04
billion) in 1998-99 (Chart 2).
At
the core of the industry's expansion worldwide and in India lies
the dramatic increase in computing power being delivered at ever-decreasing
costs by the emergence and rapid transformation of microprocessor
technology. The consequent ability to process and execute a huge number
of instructions in imperceptible time spans has had revolutionary
implications. First, it has created an industry which produces the
hardware and software needed to allow individuals, organisations,
small businesses and corporations to directly exploit the benefits
of such computing power. Second, it has substantially transformed
other industries, which can now use the capacity to store information
and execute instructions to automate and change the manner in which
they conduct and manage their processes and operations. Information
technology is in part revolutionary because it ensures and necessitates
the transformation of productive capacity in almost all sectors. Finally,
it leads to a dramatic expansion of the size and scope of the services
sector (across a wide spectrum including finance, banking, trade,
entertainment and education). This results partly from associated
technological developments that find new uses for the massive computing
power that is cheaply available, partly from the huge market that
developments in communications and networking technology create, and
partly from the fact that the increasingly ubiquitous PC becomes the
vehicle to deliver a range of services, besides being a device in
its own right. The microprocessor is not just the core of the IT revolution,
but stands at the centre of the convergence of the information, communication
and entertainment sectors.
But it is not just this remarkable and wide-ranging expansion of the
information technology sector that generates the new optimism with
regard to the prospects for developing countries within the current
world order. That optimism also stems from the understanding that,
unlike the 'routinised'
technologies which dominated development during the immediate post-World
War II years, the new 'entrepreneurial' technologies driving
the IT sector are seen as being characterised by a knowledge-base
for innovation, which is more rapidly transmitted across the globe,
and levels of investment that are much lower and often easily afforded
by even private investors in developing countries. This facilitates
entry by small players from developing countries into a rapidly expanding
segment of the global economy. Further, since much of IT production
from assembly to software generation is skilled-labour intensive,
the availability of cheap skilled labour in countries like India is
seen as giving them a decisive edge in the international competitive
battle in this sector.
Routinised
technologies, such as those characteristic of the 'older'
steel and chemical industries, were embodied in large continuous process
plants requiring 'lumpy' investments in innovation, commercialisation,
capacity creation and market acquisition. This made access to a critical
size of capital crucial for entry, queering the pitch for the big
players from the developed industrial countries. Moreover, dramatic
innovations in these sectors were few and far between, with much technological
development consisting of marginal changes that were cumulatively,
rather than instantaneously , significant. These marginal changes
were, in turn, very often stimulated by knowledge gained in the act
of production, which led up to expensive R&D exercises that created
new commercially-usable knowledge. Thus not only were these industries
dominated by big firms created with lumpy investments, but much of
the technological change that occurred in the industry originated
within or as a result of the activitiy of these big firms themselves.
Entry into the industry by new, especially small new, players was
rare. Competition was restricted to that between the dominant oligopolistic
firms straddling domestic and world markets. To the extent that technological
change could trigger a competitive challenge from outside the industry,
this was largely the result of the emergence of substitute products
or wholly new industries that rendered the older industries less significant
or even irrelevant.
As
compared with this the IT sector is seen as characterised by low costs
of entry and an easily accessed and almost universally available knowledge-base
for innovation. What is of special significance is that the sources
of this knowledge in a significant segment of the hardware and almost
all of the software segments of the industry are conventional routes
such as journals, conferences, seminars and publicly or privately
financed training programmes. This makes it easy for wholly new entrants
to acquire the knowledge base required for cutting edge technological
contributions to the industry, as was and is true of at least some
of the myriad start-ups in Silicon Valley. It is also true, that the
production of a range of products varying from components like printed
circuit boards to peripherals like modems, on the one hand, and the
assembly of personal computers, on the other, do not require large
investments for entry. These, unlike other IT products, are heterogenous
products that can be put together on the basis of a combination of
internally produced and externally sourced intermediates and components.
The real 'technology' here is a system architecture that maximises the benefit derived from an appropriate combination of sub-systems,
components and peripherals. That is, the heterogenous nature of the
product allows a producer to restrict his own production activity
to a sub-set of the total elements that enter the product and/or just
the design and assembly of the final product. This requires that the
technology in the sense of the knowledge for system design is freely
available and is easily appropriated. But once such technology is
available, the investment required for entry can be kept to the minimum,
with labour intensive assembly often involving negligible investment
in capital equipment. This allows for the emergence of international
brands from the developing world, as is true of Acer from Taiwan.
The
logic of easy entry is even more true of the software sector, which
is skilled-labour intensive and requires little by way of capital
investment. Not surprisingly, over the years the software segment
of the IT sector has come to dominate the industry in India. As Chart
3, which details the structure of the Indian IT industry in 1999-00
shows, software production accounts for two-thirds of the turnover
of the industry. However, with software exports accounting for 45
per cent of the turnover, it should be clear that hardware sales marginally
dominate the domestic market. But with software exports growing at
a much faster rate (57 per cent in 1999-00) than domestic IT expenditure
(30 per cent), it should be obvious that the industry would soon be
almost overwhelmed by software production. And, software is the segment
where the advantages of easy technology access and low entry-level
investments are most prevalent.
As
mentioned earlier, in the past, these special characteristics of the
IT sector, which substantially reduce technological and financial
barriers to entry by small players, were seen as underlying the success
of small Silicon Valley start-ups. Those start-ups not only challenged
traditional giants like IBM, but have since grown to become major
players in their own right and have changed the structure of the industry.
The growth of the IT industry in India and elsewhere in the developing
world and India's success as a software exporter, seem to suggest
that these characteristics hold for firms in developing countries
as well. Not surprisingly, it is now being argued that what was true
for the Silicon Valley start-ups in terms of their ability to break
through barriers to entry should be true for the developing countries.
It is this perception that underlies the optimism that information
technology heralds a new era of reduced international inequality.
It
should be obvious that this argument cannot be extended beyond a point,
especially in the hardware sector. The core of the computing business
is dominated by a capital-intensive and oligpolised product like the
microprocessor, the market for which is dominated by a few producers
like Intel, Motorola and AMD. And the technologies driving a range
of peripherals like printers and networking products, for example,
are proprietory and are not replicated without a licence. Further,
while capital investment requirements for production may be small,
production for geographically and quantitatively large national and
world markets require high sunk costs. This takes the form of initial
expenditures on marketing, retailing and the creation of an after-sales
service network. Deep pockets and/or access to large sums of capital
are therefore a prerequisite for entry into this segment of the hardware
sector.
This
has resulted in an unusual situation in the PC market in countries
like India, where there are a few international brand names like IBM,
Compaq, Dell, and HP, selling at a premium, while there are a number
of cheaper and exclusively national and local brands. It needs to
be noted that, barring a few exceptions like Acer and Samsung, most
international brands originate in the developed countries. These branded
products service a premium market which is willing to pay a price
for the reliability of branded products and for the assurance of quality
after-sales service that come with them. But as the PC market grows
and brings into its fold a large number of small businesses and home
users, price becomes an issue among a large share of consumers, creating
a separate market segment serviced by small assemblers. In India for
example, during the first six months of 1998-99, PC assemblers accounted
for a 53 per cent share of units sold in the Indian market and 45
per cent of the value of that market (Chart 4).
However,
most of these assemblers were extremely small in terms of the number
of unirts produced (Chart 5). This must mean that the margins in this
extremely competitive market must be extremely small. On the other
hand, as Table 1 shows, the branded products market was dominated
by international brands, with only few Indian players like HCL, Zenith,
Wipro and Vintron. In fact with liberalisation, many of the larger
domestic players like Wipro have become sales agents for international
brands like Acer and Apple, rather than producers of PCs themselves.
Needless
to say, with imported components accounting for a substantial share
of the value of PCs assembled by both the international players and
domestic assemblers, the domestic linkage effects of the growth of
PC sales could only be limited. Much more employment is likely to
be created by the growing demand for maintaining and servicing the
installed PC base (estimated at 4.3 million). Further, besides low
overheads, one of the advantages enjoyed by domestic assemblers was
allegedly their ability to avoid payments of a range of duties, especially
customs duties. However, as India's opportunities for software
exports have grown, there has been substantial pressure on the government
to liberalise imports of computer hardware and reduce import tariffs
substantially. With the government having succumbed to this pressure,
a part of the competitive advantage of assemblers has been eroded
so that we can expect the share of the larger international players
to increase substantially. This would be all the more true as the
market for 'higher end' products like notebooks and servers
increase (Chart 6). In the event, not only would the linkage effects
of the growth of the PC market be minimal but whatever value is added
domestically would accrue in the hands of large international firms.
These
features of the PC market, which would be even more true of the peripherals
market, indicate that, in the wake of liberalisation, the emergence
of a strong indigenous industry that engages world markets is not
likely in the hardware segment. Thus, if the case that India is likely
to emerge an IT powerhouse which invades developed country markets
and challenges developed-country players is valid at all, it can only
be true of the software segment.
However,
while the aggregate figures on software exports are indeed remarkable,
a closer look indicates that a few players operating at the lower
end of the value-chain in software production account for much of
these export revenues. The IT sector's software revenue in 1999-00
amounted to Rs. 24,350 crore, of which Rs. 15,890 crore came from
the export market. Around 1250 companies were involved in activities
that helped garner this export revenue. However, only 37 of them had
an export turnover of more than Rs.100 crore. The top 5 exporters
(TCS, Wipro, Infosys, Satyam and HCL) alone accounted for 29 per cent
of total exports. And the largest exporter, Tata Consultancy Services,
garnered revenues of Rs. 1,820 crore from the export of software services.
The export sector is dominated by a few players.
What is noteworthy,
however, ia that even the big exporters obtained little by way of
revenues from frontline software products or higher end consultancy
and software generation services. To quote a senior executive from
the Indian software sector: India, somewhere down the line,
has to make up its mind whether it would be a quality software developer
or concentrate on quantity
If you look at the typical structure
of the IT services provided to any of the global companies
on the bottom layer is outsourcing, above it software development,
on top of that is technology development and higher up is networking
services and, finally, IT consulting. As you move up, you get higher
billing rates, higher revenues, higher gross margins and, thereby,
high profitability because the complexity of the transaction is higher.
According to industry insiders like Naraya Murthy of Infosys, this
move up the value chain has hardly occurred and is not India's
priority. In a recent interview Murthy said Indian software expertise
in customised services had a long way to go in quantity and quality
before focusing entirely on other fields. ``Yes, moving up the value
chain is a good idea. We are at it ourselves - about Rs. 20 crores,
which is just 8 per cent of our total business and not the main,''
he said. There are others, line Vinay Deshpande of NCore who feel
that while software services should not be sneered at, the contract
should be properly designed. ``If the job is just another cover for
body shopping, then there is little technology that accrues to the
contractor
Except a few, such contracts mainly mean deputing
engineers from here. The parent company does not get any fresh infusion
of technology in this case. I strongly believe that even in service
industries, contracts should be such that there is technological upgradation.''
He feels technology thus acquired could then be leveraged to develop
indigenous products for, in the long run, the money is in developing
products.
The
difficulty is that the move up the value chain may not be a matter
of pure choice, but structurally limited. While there have been instances
of Indian companies delivering high-end products, like the banking
and e-commerce software product, BankAway, from Infosys, the industry
generally accepts that much of the exports from India consists of
low end outsourcing and IT enabled services. This limited success
in terms of the composition of exports may be because there indeed
are barriers to entry into higher end software.
Take
the case of software products for mass use for example. Creating such
a product starts identifying a felt need (say, for a browser once
the internet was opened up to the less computer savvy or for a web-publishing
programme once the internet went commercial). The persons/firms identifying
such a need must work out a strategy of generating the product, by
hiring software engineers, at the lowest cost in the shortest possible
time. Once out, the effort must be to make the product a proprietary,
industry standard. This involves winning a large share of the target
consumers, so that the product becomes the industry standard in its
area. Once done, the product becomes a revenue generating profit centre.
The investment required is the sums involved in setting up the company,
in investing in software generation during the gestation period, and
in marketing the product once it is out so as to quickly win it a
large share of the market. Needless to say, while entry by individuals
or small players are not restricted by technology, they could be limited
by the lack of seed capital. This is where the venture capitalists
enter, betting sums on start-ups which if successful could give them
revenues and capital gains that imply enormous returns.
There
are, however, two problems here. The first is one of maintaining a
monopoly on the idea during the stage when the idea is being translated
into a product. The second is that of ensuring that once the product
is in the public domain it is not replicated by competitors who win
the market before the originator of the idea consolidates. It is here
that a feature of 'entrepreneurial technologies'
the easy acquisition and widespread prevalence of the knowledge base
needed to generate new products - considered an advantage for small
new entrants actually proves a disadvantage.
There
are two aspects of technology that are crucial in this regard. First,
their source. Second, the appropriability of the benefits of a technology.
As mentioned earlier, in industries with routinised technologies the
source of technology was in significant part the activity of incumbent
firms themselves. On the other hand, in the case of entreprenurial
technologies the sources were in the public domain. This was where
the advantage lay for the small operator. But once a technology is
generated based on some expenditure in the form of sunk costs, there
must be some way in which the innovator can recoup these costs and
earn a profit as incentive to undertake the innovation. In the Schumpeterian
world this occurred because of the 'pioneer profits' that
the innovator obtained. The lead time required to replicate a technology
itself provides the original innovator with a monopoly for a period
of time that generates the surplus which warrants innovation.
Most
often this alone is not enough to warrant innovation and in the software
sector lead times can be extremely low, especially if the competitor
invests huge sums in software generation, reducing the lead time substantially.
It is for this reason that researchers have defended and invoked the
benefits of patents and barriers to entry in production, which allow
innovators to stave off competition during the period when sunk costs
are being recouped. Unfortunately, neither are the status of patents
and copyrights in the software area clear ( as illustrated by the
failure of Apple to win propietary rights over icons in user interfaces),
nor are their barriers to entry into software production.
This
has had two implications. First, the importance of secrecy in the
software business. The 'idea' behind the product must be
kept secret right through the development stage, if not competitors
can begin rival product developments even before the original product
is in the market. A feeble attempt to institutionally guarantee such
secrecy is the now infamous 'non-disclosure agreements'
which prospective employees, financiers and suppliers are called upon
to sign by the innovator who is forced to partially or fully reveal
his idea. Secondly, even after the product is out, since the threat
of replication remains, it is necessary to strive to sustain the monopoly
that being a pioneer generates. This requires 'locking in'
users with the help of an appropriate user interface which they become
accustomed to and are reticent to migrate away from, and locking in
producers of supportive software with an appropriate 'applications
programming interface'. It should be obvious that sustaining
monopoly to recoup sunk costs can indeed be difficult.
Such
strategies did help the early start-ups, resulting in the jeans-to-riches
stories (Microsoft, Netscape, etc.) with which Silicon Valley abounds.
But more recently it has become clear that start-ups undertake innovative
activities only to create winning products that the big fish acquire.
This is because of the possibility of easy replication and development
of an original product, which can be done by dominant firms with deep
pockets that allow them to stay in place and spend massively to win
dominant market shares. In the event, the likelihood that a small
start-up would be able to recoup sunk costs, clear debts and make
a reasonable profit is indeed low. Selling out ensures that such sums
can indeed be garnered.
Given
this feature of the software products market, it is not surprising
that small players (such as Netscape and Vermeer Technologies that
delivered Frontpage) are mere transient presences in key areas even
in the developed countries. To expect developing country producers
to fare better is to expect far too much. The latter can merely be
software suppliers or outsourcers for the dominant players.
What
is disconcerting is that even as outsources India still remains a
lower-end supplier of IT-enabled services. This involves not just
body-shopping in the form of temporary export of software professionals
to undertake specific jobs in large projects designed and executed
in the West, but the sale of cheap skilled and not-so-skilled labour
services whose output is transmitted via modern commucation technologies
to sites where those services are required. That is, there are a whole
host of services that can now be provided without having to move the
person supplying the service to the point where the service is being
delivered. Typical examples are a range of backoffice services and
medical transcription.
The
possibility of such service delivery has helped India circumvent the
obstacle to service exports created by immigration laws in the developed
countries. That is, a large part of software exports is not very different
from the exports of nursing, carpentry, masonry and other such services,
except for the fact that unlike those exports, the presence of the
service provider at the point of sale is not required in the case
of IT enabled servcies.
Seen
in this light, conceptually, India's software thrust of the 1990s
is not as spectacular as it appears. It is substantially a technology-aided
expansion of the of the waves of migration by services providers of
different descriptions: doctors, nurses, and blue-collared workers
of various kinds. An expansion of that kind cannot be the basis for
the redressal of international inequality that it is made out to be.
But that is not all. Even in quantitative terms this development is
not spectacular. The 'net foreign exchange revenue' to the
country from migration of the old kind, captured by the volume of
remittances into India, is in the range of $10-12 billion. The gross
foreign exchange revenue from software exports is just $4 billion.
The real question is, whether India can continue to exploit the possibilities
of arbitrage generated by differences in software and IT-enable service
costs between onsite sources and offshore centres, so as to more than
triple its current gross revenues. That possibility is threatened
not merely by the emergence of alternative offshore centres, but also
by a reduction in the onsite-offshore cost differential. It is for
this reason that industry-insiders keep emphaising the importance
of moving up the value chain in software production. But
that movement is possible as structurally constrained as the effort
at increasing sophisticated manufactured exports from the developing
to the developed world was.
|