If the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves is
any indication, India's external balance of payments
appears extremely robust. In the net there is far more
foreign exchange flowing into the country than flowing
out. As a result, the year 2002 ended with foreign
exchange reserves crossing the $70 billion mark.
This trend represents a substantial acceleration of
the rate of growth of reserves, which rose from $20 to
$30 billion over a period of more than four years
ending December 1998 and from there to $40 billion
over a two-year period ending December 2000.
Subsequently, the pace of reserves accumulation has
been even more pronounced, as Chart 1 indicates.
Between March 2001 and December 2002, external
reserves increased by $28 billion. Most of that
increase has in turn been concentrated in the past
calendar year alone, which has seen an increase in the
level of foreign exchange reserves of more than $22
billion.
Such a dramatic increase is unprecedented in the
history of Indian balance of payments. It has been
taken advantage of, by Indian policy makers, to
suggest that all is well on the macroeconomic front.
Even more significantly, the higher level of foreign
reserves is being used to argue that the country's
external accounts are now so healthy, that the economy
is ripe for a major dose of capital account
liberalisation.
This makes it important to consider the causes of this rapid
accumulation of reserves, as well as the future implications of the
forces underlying this increase.
Factors driving the increase in
foreign exchange reserves
While a part of the increase in reserves is the result
of a revaluation of the dollar value of non-dollar
foreign currency holdings, as a result of the
depreciation of the dollar against other currencies,
especially the Euro and the Yen, it is substantially
due to an excess of inflows over outflows. Even an
overgenerous estimate suggests that over the period
April to September 2002 only about $2.5 billion of the
9 billion dollar reserve accumulation was the result
of such revaluation.
Interestingly the acceleration in the pace of reserve
accretion occurred despite the fact that the
government had in August 1998 and November 2000 issued
the Resurgent India Bonds and the India Millennium
Bonds respectively, which together resulted in an
inflow of close to $9 billion in foreign exchange.
Despite the lack of any concerted effort in recent
times to mobilise foreign exchange through large scale
borrowing against bonds and indications that both the
government and the private sector are retiring and
reducing their holding of high cost foreign debt, the
RBI has been forced to mop up foreign exchange inflows
to prevent any undue appreciation of the rupee.
The RBI's efforts notwithstanding, the rupee has
indeed been appreciating, nudging its way "upwards"
from above Rs. 49 to the dollar to below Rs. 48 to the
dollar. This could be seen as reflective of the
strength of the rupee and the growing weakness of the
dollar. But appreciation of the currency in a country
that has not been able to trigger any major export
explosion despite ten years of neoliberal economic
reform is not necessarily a good sign. At given
prices, appreciation of a country's currency by
definition increases the dollar value of its exports
and reduces the local currency value of its imports.
Inasmuch as this triggers an increase in the dollar
value of imports and a decrease in the dollar value of
exports, appreciation can be damaging for the balance
of trade. And since this occurs in India at a time
when oil prices are hardening internationally, the
rupee's appreciation does threaten to widen the
balance of trade deficit, or the excess of imports of
goods and services over exports of goods and services.
There are two reasons why this has as yet not given
cause for worry to the government. First, the most
recent figures on exports point to some recovery in
India's export performance. Thus the dollar value of
India's exports rose by 15.7 per cent during the first
eight months of the current financial year
(April-November), which compares well with the
performance during the corresponding period of the
previous year.
This has tended to dampen concerns about the possible
damaging effects of exchange rate appreciation, but
this may be excessively optimistic. It is well-known
that changes in exchange rates take some time to feed
into goods markets and therefore exports and imports.
Since the rupee appreciation is still quite recent, it
will not yet have fed into changed dollar prices (with
corresponding effects on export volumes) or lower
margins faced by exporters.
Further, this improved export performance cannot be
held responsible for the improvement in India's
reserves position. A sharp 21 per cent increase in the
dollar value of oil imports and a unexpected 12 per
cent increase in the dollar value of non-oil imports
have actually increased the size of the trade deficit
recorded during the first eight months of this
financial year ($6247.65 million) as compared with the
corresponding figure for the previous year ($5814.93
million).
The second reason why the rupee's appreciation has not
given the government and the central bank cause for
concern is the role of invisibles and service payments
in easing the current generally. As a result of a $1.3
billion increase in Private Transfers (largely
remittances) and a $1.5 billion increase in net
receipts from Miscellaneous Factor Services (which
includes software and business services exports), the
current account of the balance of payments recorded a
surplus of $1.7 billion during April-September 2002-03
as compared with a deficit of $1.5 billion during the
corresponding months of 2001-02.
This means that the relatively new tendency for the
current account of the balance of payments to record a
surplus noted over the whole financial year 2001-02,
has persisted and gathered strength during the first
six months of 2002-03. All this is indicated in Chart
2, which shows the recent behaviour of major items of
current account balances.
But even allowing for this increase in the current
account surplus and after taking account of the
possible effects of dollar depreciation on value of
reserves, there remains around $ 5 billion dollars of
reserve accretion that remains to be explained even
for the April-November 2002 period. What is more,
since the balance of payments statistics indicate that
there was a net outflow of $2.2 billion on account of
repayment of external assistance and commercial
borrowing, we must account for more than $7 billion of
inflows on the capital account if reserve accumulation
during that period is to be explained.
The RBI's Balance of Payments statistics suggest that
about $1.3 billion of this is on account of foreign
investment, another $1.4 billion on account of NRI
deposits, around $1 billion on account of Other
Banking Capital, $2.1 billion on account of Other
Capital and $1.4 billion on account of "errors and
omissions".
Considering the period April-September only, it is
evident that the more recent period evidenced a slight
decline in FDI and portfolio investment flows compared
to the same period in the previous year, as Chart 3
shows. However, as Chart 4 indicates, there was a
substantial increase in 2001-02 in banking capital
flows (especially NRI deposits, largely related to the
special schemes for NRIs) that has continued into the
subsequent year. The total capital account, therefore, experienced
increases in both 2000-01 and 2001-02, as shown in Chart 5.
Implications of the large
capital inflows
What all this suggests is that large "autonomous
capital inflows”, occurring at a time when India's
requirements of capital inflows to finance any deficit
on the current account have vanished, have played a
major role in explaining reserve accumulation. And
inasmuch as the easy availability of dollars on
account of such inflows have resulted in an
appreciation of rupee's value in India's liberalized
exchange markets, this has also affected the speed
with which export earning as being repatriated.
Exporters, who in the past preferred to delay
repatriation of receipts in order to benefit from any
depreciation of the rupee, have been keen on bringing
back their dollar receipts in order not to lose out on
the rupee value of receipts because of the
appreciation of the domestic currency. Such delayed
repatriation of exports receipts get included
according the RBI under the "errors and omissions"
head.
Thus when we breakdown dollar receipts by source, it
becomes clear that the robust balance of payments
position - as indicated by reserve accumulation and
currency appreciation - is largely due to autonomous
flows from abroad. Those autonomous flows result in a
tendency towards currency appreciation, which has a
peculiar effect on export receipts. In the short run,
by encouraging the quick repatriation of past and
current export receipts rupee appreciation increases
such receipts. But in the medium and long-term, by
raising the dollar value of India's exports it affects
export revenues adversely.
This is why it is worth bearing in mind the possible
implications of the recent appreciation of the real
effective exchange rate (for exporters, according to
35-country weights) as described in Chart 6.
If any such appreciation-induced worsening of the
balance of trade combines with other factors such as
an increase in oil prices and a rise in imports on
account of buoyancy in the domestic market, a country
can be confronted with a situation of rising reserves
and an appreciating currency precisely at a time when
trade and possibly even current account "fundamentals"
are worsening. The process can be especially damaging
if foreign investment inflows that involve servicing
costs in foreign exchange do not contribute to the
country's foreign exchange earnings.
This would be true of portfolio flows and of
acquisition of domestic companies catering to the
domestic market by foreign firms. It is also true of
foreign direct investment flows into joint venture
companies catering to the domestic market where the
existing foreign partner seeks to use the benefits of
liberalisation to increase equity share. These are the
principal forms of foreign investment flows into
India. Despite all this, fortunately, India is still
not in such a situation where this has damaged its
balance of payments, as we have seen earlier.
Yet there is a cause for concern for a number of
reasons. Virtually pushed by the embarrassingly large
level of reserves, and unable to keep acquiring
dollars from the market in order to prevent the rupee
from appreciating too fast, the central bank has
accelerated liberalization of rules relating to
availability of foreign exchange for both current
account and a growing set of capital account
transactions.
Easier access of foreign exchange for travel,
education and the like, slack rules governing use of
international credit cards, increase in the limits to
which foreign exchange can be used by importers
without RBI clearance and changes in rules regarding
hedging of foreign exchange transactions are all signs
of a process of creeping liberalisation. The thrust is
clearly in the direction of encouraging use of foreign
exchange and liberalizing rules governing cross border
movements of goods and capital.
In fact, discussion on moving towards full
convertibility of the rupee, as recommended by the
Tarapore Committee, which had been shelved after the
East Asian crises, has once again revived. The most
recent changes in policy suggest that full capital
account convertibility is not just on the agenda, it
is almost completed in terms of the government's own
strategy.
Consider the policy changes – some of which have
far-reaching implications – which have already
occurred in the past two months alone. On 1 November
2002, resident Indians were allowed to maintain
resident foreign currency accounts in domestic banks.
On November 18, the Reserve Bank of India doubled the
foreign exchange available under the Basic Travel
Quota to resident Indians, from $5,000 per trip to
$10,000 per trip.
On December 12 another package of measures were
announced. These included allowing banks to offer
foreign currency-rupee swaps without any limit.
Exporters and importers were allowed to book forward
contracts up to value of average turnover, without any
documents (subject to a limit to $100 million). Banks
were allowed to offer forward cover to Non-Resident
entities on FDI deployed after 1993. Further, domestic
banks were permitted to invest any amount in overseas
money market and debt instruments.
On January 10, 2003, yet another set of liberalising
measures was announced, that has brought the economy
even closer to capital account convertibility. These
include a general permission granted to companies
issuing GDRs and ADRs, to retain the receipts abroad.
Up to $1 million can now be remitted abroad for
transfer of assets in India. The limit on remittances
under of ESOP (which was $20,000) has been removed.
Similarly, the limit on trade-related loans and
advances by EEFC account holder has been discontinued.
There have been further measures easing the ability to
export capital. Indian Mutual funds have been allowed
to invest $1 billion in companies listed overseas that
have at least 10 per cent holding in a locally listed
company. Even individuals have been allowed to invest
in such overseas companies, with some limits.
Companies have been permitted to acquire immovable
property overseas for business and staff housing
purposes. Listed companies have been allowed to invest
in those overseas firms that have at least 10 per cent
stake in an India company, with a limit of 10 per cent
of net worth of the Indian company, for such
investment.
These measures bring the economy much closer to
liberal capital account transactions, and make it much
more difficult for the government to regulate or even
monitor the nature of a range of transactions which
may also involve the flow of speculative capital.
While the government still retains some degree of
control on external commercial borrowing by firms,
this is not the only form of mobile finance capital
that can cause broader macro-economic problems.
Unfortunately, such liberalisation can aggravate
rather than resolve the problem currently confronting
the government. It is to be expected that when a
country with a relatively liberalised trading
environment experiences currency appreciation,
incentives to investors in that country to produce
tradable commodities that can be exported or are
substitutes for imports decline relative to the
incentive to invest in activities involving the
generation of non-tradable goods or services. The
desires to borrow abroad to invest in infrastructural
activities producing non-tradable services, to invest
in real estate and construction and to invest in the
stock market, all increase substantially.
This most often leads to excess capacity in certain
infrastructure areas and even sets off a speculative
boom in real estate and stock markets. It also means
that there is an inflow of foreign exchange into the
country, the costs of which would have to be serviced
in time in foreign exchange. Finally, it means that
while it increases dependence on foreign capital
inflows, it also increases the risk that such flows
can dry up and that past inflows are rapidly
repatriated. That is why it is increasingly recognised
across the world that the control and regulation of
capital inflows may be even more significant in
staving off potential crises, than controls on
outflow.
Indeed, reserve accumulation and currency appreciation
of the kind that India is experiencing, the factors
that underlie those tendencies and the government's
liberalising response to the tendencies are
reminiscent of the process by which countries that
were relatively healthy in East Asia and Latin America
were pushed into crisis. This curious similarity makes
India's remarkable dollar reserve even more noteworthy
than it is being made out to be. It could be the first
sign of a crisis that India has managed to stave off
thus far, and ironically it would have been caused by
the very factors that the government is currently
celebrating, such as the accumulation of external
reserves.