During the 1990s, the three-decade long process of
proliferation and rise to dominance of finance in the global economy
reached a new phase. On the one hand, evidence was growing that the
rise of finance, and the financial liberalization it encouraged and
enforced, was resulting in financial instability of a kind that was
undermining the real economic gains registered in different parts of
the world since the Second World War. On the other hand, the international
financial system was being transformed in directions that were substantially
increasing systemic risk, and rendering the system more crisis-prone.
Central to this transformation was a growing process of financial consolidation
that is concentrating financial activity and financial decision making
in a few economic organizations and integrating hitherto demarcated
areas of financial activity that had been dissociated from each other
to ensure transparency and discourage unsound financial practices.
Concerned with the consequences
and implications of this process Finance ministers and Central Bank
Governors of the Group of 10 commissioned a study of financial consolidation,
the recently released results of which are quite revealing. The study
covered besides the 11 G-10 countries (US, Canada, Japan, Belgium, France,
Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland and UK), Spain and
Australia. It found, as expected, that there has been a high level of
merger and acquisition (M&A) activity in the study countries during
the 1990s, with an acceleration of such activity especially in the last
three years of the decade.
As Chart 1 shows, The number
of acquisitions by financial firms from these countries increased from
around 337 in 1990 to over 900 by 1995, and has more or less remained
between 900 and 1000 a year since then. What is more the size of each
of these acquisitions has increased substantially since the mid-1990s.
The total value of financial sector M&A initiated by firms in these
countries, which stood at $39 billion in 1990 and $53 billion in 1994,
rose three-fold to $154 billion in 1995 and $299 billion, $499 billion
and $369 billion respectively in 1997, 1998 and 1999 respectively (Chart
2). This was because the average value of the M&A instances covered
rose from just $224 million and $111 million in 1990 and 1994, to touch
$504 million, $793 million and $649 million respectively during the
last three years of the decade (Chart 3). As a result the annual value
of M&A transactions, which stood at less than 0.5 per cent of the
GDP of these nations in the early 1990s, had risen to as much as 2.3
per cent of their GDP in 1998. Clearly, M&A in the financial sector
is creating large and complex financial organizations in the international
financial system (Chart 4).
The banking sector tended
to dominate the M&A process in the financial sector, accounting
for as much as 58 per cent of the value of M&A during the 1990s
as a whole, as compared with 27 per cent in the case of securities
and other firms and 15 per cent in the case of the insurance industry
(Chart 6). However, a closer look at the evolution of M&A activity
through the 1990s suggests that while the instances of M&A in the
banking industry were rising rapidly during the first half of the 1990s,
they have tended to stagnate, while instances of M&A among securities
and insurance firms have been on the rise. As a result, by the end of
the 1990s, the number of instances of M&A among non-banking financial
firms was almost as large as those among banking firms. The process
of concentration is clearly sweeping through the financial sector as
a whole (Chart 5). However, given the large size of the banks as financial
institutions, the banking industry dominates financial sector merger
activity in value terms (Charts 7 and 8).
Over the 1990s as a whole
the evidence seems to be that M&A activity was largely industry-specific,
with banking firms tending to merge dominantly with other banks (Charts
13 and 14). However, matters seem to be changing here as well. While
in 1994 there was one instance of cross-industry M&A for every five
instances of intra-industry mergers, the ratio had come down to one
in every three by 1999. The merger and acquisition drive within the
financial sector is not merely creating large and excessively powerful
organizations, but firms that straddle the financial sector. Exploiting
the process of financial liberalization these firms were breaking down
the Chinese Walls that had been built between different segments of
the financial sector.
Needless to say, in terms
of region North America, especially the US, which has become the apex
of financial dominance, accounted for a overwhelming share of M&A
activity in the study countries in terms of both numbers and value (Charts
9 and 10). Europe was a close second. And given the much larger and
more dispersed financial sector in the US, as well the compulsions generated
by monetary union in Europe, M&A activity in North America was dominated
by intra-country, within-border transactions, whereas cross-border
M&A played a much more important role in Europe (Charts 11 and 12).
But as the report notes, through strategic alliances the American financial
industry has also spread its tentacles across the globe. In the net,
the 1990s have seen an acceleration of the concentration of financial
power and financial decision-making in fewer hands worldwide.
The
significance of these developments for the observed financial instability
and recurrence of financial crises during the years of globalisation
should be obvious. The major historical landmarks in the rise to dominance
of finance are worth recalling. Till the early 1970s the private international
financial system played only a limited role in recycling financial surpluses
to the developing countries. The period immediately after the first
oil shock saw a dramatic change in this scenario. Since oil surpluses
were held in the main as deposits with the international banking system
controlled in the developed world, the private financial system there
became the powerful agent for recycling surpluses. This power was indeed
immense. Expenditure fuelled by credit in the developed and developing
world generated surpluses with the oil producers, who then deposited
these surpluses with the transnational banks, who, in turn, could offer
further doses of credit. By 1981, OPEC countries are estimated to have
accumulated surpluses to the tune of $475 billion, $400 billion of which
was parked in the developed industrial nations. This power to the finance
elbow was all the more significant because a slow down in productivity
growth in metropolitan industry had already been bringing the post-War
industrial boom to a close - a process that was hastened by the contractionary
response to the oil shocks. As a proportion of world output, net international
bank loans rose from 0.7 per cent in 1964 to 8.0 per cent in 1980 and
16.3 per cent in 1991. Relative to world trade, net international bank
loans rose from 7.5 per cent in 1964 to 42.6 per cent in 1980 and 104.6
per cent in 1991.
Two other developments contributed
to the increase in international liquidity during the 1980s. First,
the United States had built up large international liabilities during
the Bretton Woods years, when the confidence in the dollar stemming
from the immediate post-War hegemony of the US made it as good as gold.
Such international confidence in its currency allowed the US to ignore
national budget constraints on its international spending and resulted
in the emergence of strong banking and financial interests with an international
agenda. The influence of these interests was reflected in policies that
affected domestic manufacturing interests adversely, as suggested by
the widening and persistent US trade deficit after the mid-1970s. Second,
the loss of manufacturing competitiveness in the US meant that during
different periods since the 1970s the dollar lost its position as the
only acceptable reserve currency, fuelling speculative demand for other
currencies on the part of those holding them. Such speculative demand,
needless to say, is sensitive to both interest rate differentials and
exchange rate variations, resulting in volatile flows of capital across
currencies and borders. The results of these developments are obvious.
The daily volume of foreign exchange transactions in international financial
markets rose to $1.2 trillion per day by the mid-1990s, which was equal
to the value of world trade in every quarter of a full year. In the
early 1980s the volume of transactions of bonds and securities between
domestic and foreign residents accounted for about 10 per cent of GDP
in the US, Germany and Japan. By 1993 the figure had risen to 135 per
cent for the US, 170 per cent for Germany and 80 per cent for Japan.
Much of these transactions were of bonds of relatively short maturities.
There
were also other real factors that created pressures for the expansion
of finance. These included the changing demographic structure in most
of the advanced countries, with baby boomers reaching the age when they
would emphasise personal savings for retirement. This was accentuated
by changes in the institutional structures relating to pensions, whereby
in most industrial countries, public and private employers tended to
fund less of the planned income after retirement, requiring more savings
input from employees themselves. All this meant growing demands for
more variety in savings instruments as well as higher returns, leading
to the greater significance of pensions funds, mutual funds and the
like.
Financial
liberalisation in the developed countries, which was closely related
to these developments, further increased funds available in the system.
First, it increased the flexibility of banking and financial institutions
when creating credit and making investments, as well as permitted the
proliferation of institutions like the hedge funds that, unlike the
banks, were not subject to regulation. It also provided the space for
"financial innovation" or the creation of a range of new financial
instruments or derivatives such as swaps, options and futures that were
virtually autonomously created by the financial system. Finally, it
increased competition and whetted the appetite of banks to earn higher
returns, thus causing them to search out new recipients for loans in
different economic regions.
The massive increase in international
liquidity that followed found banks and non-bank financial institutions
desperately searching for means to keep their capital moving. At first,
there were booms in consumer credit and housing finance in the developed
industrial nations. But when those opportunities petered out, a number
of developing countries were discovered as the "emerging markets"
of the global financial order. Capital in the form of debt and equity
investments began to flow into these countries, especially those that
were quick to liberalize rules relating to cross-border capital flows
and regulations governing the conversion of domestic into foreign currency
The result of these developments was that there was a host of new financial
assets in the emerging markets, which were characterized by higher interest
rates ostensibly because of the greater risks of investment in these
areas. The greater perceived risk associated with financial
instruments originating in these countries, provided the basis for a
whole range of new derivatives that bundled these risks and offered
a hedge against risk in different individual markets, each of which
promised high returns.
There
are a number of features characteristic of the global financial system
which evolved in this manner. Principal among these is the growing importance
of unregulated financial agents, such as the so-called hedge funds,
in the system. Many years back the Group of 30 had cautioned governments
that these funds were a source of concern because they were prone to
"undercapitalisation, faulty systems, inadequate supervision and
human error". Though hedge funds first originated immediately after
the second world war, they are estimated to manage close to $500 billion
of investors' money. These investors include major international banks,
which are themselves forced by rules and regulations to avoid risky
transactions promising high returns, but use the hedge funds as a front
to undertake such transactions. The operations of the now infamous Long
Term Capital Management illustrate this. On an equity base of a little
less than $5 billion, LTCM had borrowed enough to undertake investments
valued at $200 billion or more. This was possible because there was
nothing in the regulatory mechanism that limited the exposure of these
institutions relative to their capital base. Yet when several of its
own investments came unstuck in 1998 and LTCM therefore faced major
repayment problems of its own, it had to be rescued by the US Federal
Reserve, because the costs of its collapse were seen to be too major.
Such
flows of credit to a few institutions are significant because in a world
of globalized and liberalised finance, when countries are at different
phases of the business cycle and characterised by differential interest
rates, capital will tend to flow in the direction of higher returns
in the short term. Nothing illustrates this better than the "yen-carry
trades" of the period 1995 to 1997, which emerged from the wide
interest differentials between the United States and Japan, in conjunction
with the belief that the Bank of Japan did not want the yen to strengthen
in 199697. These trades involved borrowing in yen, selling the
yen for dollars, and investing the proceeds in relatively high-yielding
US fixed-income securities. In hindsight, these trades turned out to
be considerably more profitable than simply the interest differential,
for the yen depreciated continuously over the two years from May 1995
through May 1997, which reduced the yen liability relative to the dollar
investment that it financed. The implications of these and other flows
to the US was that international liquidity "was intermediated in
US financial markets and invested abroad through purchases of foreign
securities by US investors ($108 billion) and by net lending abroad
by US banks ($98 billion)."
There
are a number of points to note from these examples. To start with, the
global financial system is obviously characterised by a high degree
of centralisation. With US financial institutions intermediating global
capital flows, the investment decisions of a few individuals in a few
institutions virtually determines the nature of the "exposure"
of the global financial system. Unfortunately, unregulated entities
making huge profits on highly speculative investments are at the core
of that system. The growing consolidation in the financial sector noted
by the G-10 study increases this centralisation.
Further, once there are institutions
that are free of the now-diluted regulatory system, even those that
are more regulated are entangled in risky operations. They are entangled,
because they themselves have lent large sums in order to benefit from
the promise of larger returns from the risky investments undertaken
by the unregulated institutions. They are also entangled because the
securities on which these institutions bet in a speculative manner are
also securities that these banks hold as "safe investments".
If changes in the environment force these funds to dump some of their
holdings to clear claims that are made on them, the prices of securities
the banks directly hold tend to fall, affecting their assets position
adversely. This means that there are two consequences of the new financial
scenario: it is difficult to judge the actual volume and risk of the
exposure of individual financial institutions; and within the financial
world there is a complex web of entanglement with all firms mutually
exposed, but each individual firm exposed to differing degrees to any
particular financial entity. The increase in the incidence of cross-industry
mergers within the financial sector consolidates this tendency towards
entanglement of agents involved in sectors of financial activity characterized
by differential risk and substantially differential returns, thereby
increasing the share of high-risk assets in the portfolio of large financial
agents.
It is in this light that the
consolidation in the financial sector involving a reduction in the number
of operators, a huge increase in the size of operators at the top end
of the pyramid, and the growing integration of financial activity across
sectors and globally needs to be assessed. While the rise to dominance
of finance has been accompanied by a growing role for speculative investment
and profit, the concentration of increasingly globalized financial activity
would lead to higher share of speculative investments in the portfolio
of financial agents and greater volatility in investments worldwide
as well as make it difficult if not impossible for national regulators
to monitor the activity of these huge entities. The risk of financial
failure is now being built into the structure of the system.
This
has two kinds of consequences. First it increases systemic risk within
the financial sector itself. If transactions of the kind that led upto
the savings and loan crisis or the Barings debacle come to play a major
role in any of these large behemoths, and go unnoticed for some period
by national regulators, the risks to the system could be extreme, given
the integration of the financial system and entanglement of financial
firms. Second, once a crisis afflicts one of these agents, the process
of bailing them out may be too costly and the burden too complex to
distribute. The G-10 report is quite candid on this count. To quote
the report:
"It seems likely
that if a large and complex banking organisation became impaired, then
consolidation and any attendant complexity may have, other things being
equal, increased the probability that the work-out or wind-down of such
an organisation would be difficult and could be disorderly. Because
such firms are the ones most likely to be associated with systemic risk,
this aspect of consolidation has most likely increased the probability
that a wind-down could have broad implications.
Important reasons for this
effect include disparate supervisory and bankruptcy policies and procedures
both within and across national borders, complex corporate structures
and risk management practices that cut across different legal entities
within the same organisation, and the increased importance of market-sensitive
activities such as OTC derivatives and foreign exchange transactions.
In addition, the larger firms that result, in part, from consolidation
have a tendency either to participate in or to otherwise rely more heavily
on market instruments. Because market prices can sometimes
change quite rapidly, the potential speed of such a firms financial
decline has risen. This increased speed, combined with the greater complexity
of firms caused in substantial degree by consolidation, could make timely
detection of the nature of a financial problem more difficult, and could
complicate distinguishing a liquidity problem from a solvency problem
at individual institutions.
The importance of this concern
is illustrated by the fact that probably the most complex large banking
organisation wound down in the United States was the Bank of New England
Corp. Its USD 23.0 billion in total assets (USD 27.6 billion in 1999
dollars) in January 1991 when it was taken over by the government pale
in comparison to the total assets of the largest contemporary US firms,
which can be on the order of USD 700 billion.
The systemic risk relates
not just to the financial sector itself. It also stems from the possible
impact this would have on weaker participants in the international financial
system, such as the developing countries. Along with the globalization
of finance, financial crises in individual countries and economic regions
have become the norm. And globalization has also meant that the effects
of a crisis in one part of the world are quickly transmitted elsewhere,
making contagion a word as often referred to in financial as in medical
parlance. The number of instances of crises of significant dimensions
has been growing. To quote one set of observers, among the major crises
that have accompanied the rise of finance have been: the crisis
in the Southern Cone in the late 1970s; the Third World debt crisis
of the early 1980s; the savings and loan debacle in the US in the late
1980s; the so-call ERM crisis in 1992; the Mexican crisis of 1994-95
and its follow-on crisis in Latin America; the East Asian crisis of
1997; the Russian meltdown of 1998; and the collapse of the real
in Brazil and its impact on the rest of Latin America. Besides
these there have been crises in individual countries in the 1990s such
as in India, Argentina and Turkey. Of these instances, in all cases
where the crisis affected developing countries, the impact on the real
economy as well the large proportion of people in those countries living
at the margins of subsistence has been devastating. One only needs to
refer here to the lost decade of the 1980s in Latin America
and the evidence on unemployment, poverty and deteriorating quality-of-life
indicators in Sputheast Asia.
These and other instances
suggest that the dominance of finance has substantially increased systemic
risk in the international financial system, with extremely adverse implication
for the progress of the real economy. Yet little is being done to prevent
the autonomous transformation of the system in directions that enhance
such risk. What is more, the influence of the finance capital is so
great that despite the weight of the evidence collated by the G-10 report,
it chooses to argue against intervention in the financial sector. In
its view: The complexity and different effects of the consolidation
processes taking place within the payment and settlement industry make
it impossible to categorise consolidation either as purely positive
or as purely negative from a social welfare viewpoint
In general,
at the present stage, it does not seem to be advisable for public authorities
to interfere with the market competition between financial institutions
or between payment and settlement systems. In fact, public authorities,
as a public policy objective, may wish to remove potential obstacles
to the consolidation process when it enables the market to develop initiatives
aimed at reducing risks and enhancing efficiency in the field of payment
and securities settlement. Clearly evidence, theory and logic
are no more the determinants of public policy.
|