In an economy such as that of
India, the
generation of productive employment opportunities spread over a wide base
of population is obviously the key to any sustainable economic expansion,
as well the reduction of poverty and more equitable distribution of
income. Indeed, the inability to generate such employment, thus improving
aggregate productivity of labour in the Indian economy rather than just in
a few chosen sectors, has been the most obvious symptom of the failure of
the Indian economic development process.
The marketist economic "reforms" of the 1990s were not specifically
directed at employment, however. Despite this, the stated expectation of
policy makers over this period has been that liberalising markets, easing
the conditions for entry and operation of foreign investors and
encouraging exports especially in agriculture, would all contribute to
more employment generation. Thus, this was supposed to be a positive
fallout of the new economic strategy. And since the expansion and
diversification of rural employment in particular has been associated with
declining levels of rural poverty over the 1980s, this was also expected
to lead to a decline in poverty.
The data recently released by the National Sample Survey
Organisation allow for an investigation into all-India trends in
employment patterns and trends in poverty incidence, based on annual
surveys conducted since 1990-91. There has already been much discussion of
what the data on consumer expenditure suggest with respect to poverty, in
particular the disturbing finding that rural poverty in particular has not
declined after the reforms but may even have increased. But the observed
pattern of trends in employment have been less noted. In this piece, we
deal with rural employment patterns at the all-India level.
The annual surveys provide an important picture of how employment
generation has changed in the Indian economy in the era of reforms. It
should be noted that these annual surveys, which have been conducted since
1990-91, relate to a smaller number of households than the much larger
quinquennial surveys, the last of which was held in 1993-94. Thus they
have covered between 27,000 and 29,000 households rather than 1.3 lakh
households in the larger sample. For this reason, the results tend to be
less reliable estimates in terms of all indicators at the state level.
However, at the all-India level they continue to be statistically relevant
and reliable indicators, except possibly for those variables (such as
unemployment) for which the proportion of population is rather low.
In what follows, therefore, we consider the all-India trends only,
in terms of arriving at some idea of the trends in overall employment
generation and pattern of employment in terms of sector and type of
activity.
A further note on the definitions used in the data is in order. The
NSS data on employment is based on the distinction between "principal" and
"subsidiary" status of activity as well whether the person is "usually"
engaged in the activity. Thus, a person is classified as "usual principal
status" according to the status of the activity (or non-activity) on which
the person spent a relatively longer time of the preceding year. The
activities pursued by a person are grouped into three broad categories :
(a) working or employed (b) seeking or available for work (i.e.
unemployed) and (c) not in the labour force.
A "non-worker" (on the basis of the usual principal status) is
someone whose major part of time in the preceding year was spent as either
unemployed or not in the labour force. However, he or she could still be
involved in some economic activity in a subsidiary capacity - when this is
usually the case the person is referred to as a "subsidiary status
worker".
The two categories together - usual workers by both principal and
subsidiary status - constitute "all usual workers". In the discussion
below, we consider "all workers" - that is both principal and subsidiary,
so as to allow for a comparison over time. However, it should be noted
that this could in fact overestimate the extent of employment, on average
by around 2 per cent of the population.
The "current weekly status" definition is one which classifies a
person as employed if he/she was engaged in any one of the gainful
occupations listed for at least one hour on any one day of the previous
week. The activity assigned to the person then depends upon which activity
he/she had spent the most amount of time on. Both the usual status and the
weekly status provide stock measures of employment, but the usual status
definition is likely to be less reflective of the transient character of
the timing of the survey and be less affected by seasonal and short-run
factors.
Economic activity is defined by the NSSO as any activity that
results in the production of goods and services that adds value to the
national product. These in turn are both market activities and non-market
activities. The non-market activities encompass all activities relating to
the agricultural sector and gathering of primary produce for consumption,
and activities relating to the own account production of fixed assets such
as houses, roads and wells or even machinery for household enterprise.
It should be noted that this definition of economic activity is
still quite restrictive, and does not include the full spectrum of
economic activities defined in the UN System of National Accounts. It
therefore excludes a significant amount of unpaid or non-marketed labour
within the household, especially by women, including the processing of
primary produce for own consumption, services such as cleaning, child care
and so on, which are undertaken within the household and not marketed.
This means there is a likely underestimation of economic activity within
the household, as well as of the work participation rates especially of
women.
Charts 1 and 2 give the work force participation rates (that is,
number of all workers as a ratio of total population) for men and women in
rural
India for a
fairly long period, from the early 1970s to the late 1990s. It is evident
that the male work force participation rates have remained broadly stable
over this entire period, fluctuating within a relatively narrow band
between 54 per cent and 56 per cent. Within this, the latest period, the
first half of 1998, shows a relatively sharp decline. It should be
mentioned here that while this decline has been particularly sharp in the
younger age-bracket (5-14 years) which is a positive development, it has
also declined in other age-groups (including the most active group of
15-59 years) as well. This decline in usual status work participation is
also matched by a similar decline in terms of the weekly status definition
in 1998.
For rural females, the picture of work participation has shown a
much higher degree of fluctuation. Here it is important to remember that
while there continues to be a significant degree of underestimation of the
actual (largely unpaid) labour of women, to the extent that the current
estimates reflect the access of women to recognised productive employment,
it is an important indicator of material status.
As Chart 2 shows, the overall picture of female work force
participation in the rural areas is one of fluctuations around a declining
trend. This is surprising because the sensitivity of NSS investigators to
the possibility of women working has if anything increased by the 1990s,
so that the likelihood of under-reporting according to the prevailing
definition is less. Female work force participation rates were on average
significantly higher in the 1970s until the mid-1980s. While the 1993-94
data do show a level comparable to the 1987-88. the general pattern based
on the annual surveys shows a fairly sharp decline. The latest year in
fact shows the lowest rate over the entire period. This tendency is
extremely significant and the causes for this need to be investigated in
much more detail.
Charts 3 and 4 describe the pattern of employment for all rural
workers for males and females respectively. The picture that emerges from
both of these charts, but most strongly for male rural workers, is that
the period from 1997-78 to 1987-88 witnessed a significant decline in the
proportion of primary sector employment, and the period thereafter, and
especially over the 1990s, has indicated first a reversal of that pattern,
followed by a slight increase in the share of primary sector employment
over the 1990s.
For rural male workers, the share of primary sector employment fell
from more than 80 per cent in 1977-78 to 70 per cent by 1990-91 - a fall
of nearly ten percentage points which is a very large shift over a little
more than a decade. The shift was to both secondary and tertiary sector
activities. However, thereafter there was an increase in the share of
primary sector employment, and over the 1990s the ratio has remained
around 75 per cent, increasing slightly over the period.
For rural female workers, the picture is similar. Primary sector
employment declined from 87 per cent in 1977-78 to around 81 per cent in
1989-90 - a decline of around six percentage points. Subsequently it has
started increasing again, and stood at nearly 89 per cent by 1998. For
both men and women, the shift to primary work has been mainly at the
expense of the secondary sector, although even tertiary sector employment
is lower compared to the levels achieved at the close of the decade of the
1980s.
These trends are extremely important, because it is now widely
accepted that the diversification of rural employment away from the
primary sector to non-agricultural activities in the period 1997-78 to
1987-88 was a significant factor in the reduction of the incidence of
poverty at an all-India level.
There is now significant evidence that that the main dynamic source
of rural employment generation over the period from the mid 1970s to the
late 1980s was the external agency of the state rather than forces
internal to the rural economy. Indeed, the role of dynamic agriculture was
significant only in states such as
Punjab and Haryana where agricultural incomes had
crossed a minimum threshold and where further increases in agricultural
output were accompanied by labour displacement rather than greater labour
absorption. Outside this limited region, the pull was provided mainly by
external stimuli.
In certain very specific regions, for example along the Bombay-New
Delhi and the Bombay-Bangalore highways, industrial development and the
growth of services linked to this did make inroads into rural society by
creating new employment opportunities not only in the tertiary sector but
also in small-scale industry. In addition, in the hinterland of
industrially or commercially developed regions, there was growing
incidence of workers who lived in rural areas but commuted to urban areas
- a tendency which was enhanced by the fact that the organised sector has
tended to prefer casual workers to regular employees, and because rising
urban rents and deteriorating urban infrastructure along with falling
transport costs have influenced workers' choice of residence.
However, given the limited geographical spread of such direct links
to modern industry and commerce, in most areas the pivotal role in the
expansion of rural non-agricultural employment appears to have been played
by the expansion of government expenditure.
As noted earlier, the eighties were a period when, along with a
rapid increase in all sorts of subsidies and transfers to households from
government, there was a very large increase in expenditure on the rural
sector by State and Central governments, and this was also a period when
the expenditure on Rural Development expanded manifold. More generally,
throughout the period political developments tended to give rural
interests greater power and they were able to command an improvement in
the historically low share of government expenditure benefiting rural
areas. Although this improvement in share should not be exaggerated, an
indication may be the fact that nearly 60% of all new government jobs
created accrued to rural areas during the decade.
Moreover, NSS data suggest that, despite a low average contribution
of only around 5% of total rural employment, the government's contribution
was around a fifth when it came to either total rural non-agricultural
employment in 1987-88 or the increments in total rural employment
between 1977-78 and 1987-88. Moreover, in 1987-88, about 60% of the
regular non-agricultural employees in rural areas were employed by the
government which created almost 80% of the increments in such regular jobs
during the decade covered.
Thus, the total quantum of increased flow of public resources into
rural areas must have been significant. This flow of resources took two
predominant forms. There was, first, a fairly large expansion of `rural
development' schemes with an explicit redistributive concern. This
included not only the various rural employment and IRDP programmes but
also a plethora of special schemes for a variety of identifiable `target'
groups. Motivated by the realisation that income growth by itself would
not `trickle down' in adequate amounts, these programmes were however less
than entirely successful. They spawned a large bureaucracy and they became
a focal point for the politics of `distributive coalitions'. Yet, even
though the intended beneficiaries often got short-changed because of such
leakages, these programmes represented a fairly massive net transfer to
rural areas.
The second avenue by which resources flowed from government to
rural areas was through the greater accessibility of the rural elites to
the varied benefits of government expenditure. In part this was a result
of greater mobility due to better transport infrastructure, but to a large
extent it was also the outcome of the fact that with governments changing
frequently (particularly at the state level) more new favours, not just
jobs, but also various types of agencies and contracts, had to be
distributed more often and the rural areas got a greater than normal share
in such largesse. The resulting flow of resources and the consequent
generation of rural demand led to growing opportunities for
diversification of the self-employed from agriculture to non-agriculture.
To a very large extent, the direct access to government permanent
employment and also to many of the other resources was confined to the
better-off and more powerful groups in rural society, to whom such incomes
were more lucrative than agriculture. It should also be noted that such
access to better employment or other resources was dominantly accorded to
male workers rather than to women workers.
Associated with this was a large and significant increase in the
proportion of the 15 to 29 age cohort which continued in education rather
than join the work force. Once again, males dominantly benefited, but the
increase is evident even in the case of females, albeit to a much smaller
extent. In part this shift to higher education rather than seeking
immediate employment must have been a result of the expansion of
educational facilities as part of the general expansion of government in
rural and semi-urban areas. But this may have represented also a
motivational change (to acquire necessary qualifications for a regular
non-agricultural job) among the youth - particularly the male youth - in
the relatively well-off sections of rural society.
There was thus a movement out of agricultural work at the margin by
workers and potential workers from such better-off rural groups, which
meant that sections of the relatively rich vacated agriculture either to
obtain regular employment, mainly in the service sector, or to take up
non-agricultural self-employment. This increased the ability of members of
the less well-off rural households - including and in some areas
especially, women - to find agricultural work, and also created a demand
for certain types of rural services and industry.
However, these averages probably serve to hide very significant
differences among workers, both across regions and between groups of
relatively more privileged and more disadvantaged workers. Although such
increases in employment and wages did improve the condition of the poorest
rural workers, their employment diversification into non-agriculture
continued to have many characteristics of a "distress" process, given the
overall tendency of labour use in agriculture. Dictated by the need to
ensure economic survival, they increasingly entered into casual work not
only in agriculture but also in non-agriculture.
The main sectors providing this type of non-agricultural employment
were secondary sectors like construction, mining, and manufacturing, and
here too the agency of the state was important in terms of the effect, at
the margin, of rural employment and income generation schemes. Thus, 22.3
per cent of all casual labour days spent on non-agricultural activity in
1987-88 were on public works programmes of the government, this percentage
having increased from 17.7 in 1977-78 and 14.9 in 1983. Indeed, the
expansion of public works programmes was a critical element in increasing
both access to lean-season incomes and boosting the bargaining power of
rural labour.
This is of course an extremely schematic presentation of what is a
much more multifarious and regionally diverse scenario, and there were
variations in the pattern across states and over time. However, the fact
that the developments described above occurred in almost every state,
irrespective of the rate of growth in agriculture or organised industry,
does point to the increased importance of external stimuli to rural
employment and, in particular, the crucial role of the state. More
importantly, these trends mean that the rural labour demand is no longer
determined only by what is happening within the agricultural sector, but
is determined crucially also by macro-economic processes and policies
which do not at first appear to have any direct link with rural
well-being.
In this context, it is not difficult to see why the macro-economic
policies of the 1990s should have contributed to the reversal of two
important processes in the rural areas in the 1980s : the diversification
of employment and the reduction of poverty. The pattern of structural
adjustment and government macro-economic strategy since 1991 has been one
which has involved a continued stagnation in employment generation in the
organised sector, both public and private.
Moreover, this strategy involved the following measures which
specifically related to the rural areas :
(1) Actual declines in Central government revenue expenditure on
rural development (including agricultural programmes and rural employment
and anti-poverty schemes), such that there has been an overall decline in
per capita government expenditure on rural areas.
(2) Very substantial declines in public infrastructure and energy
investments which affect the rural areas. These have not related only to
matters like irrigation but also to transport and communications which
indirectly contribute significantly even to agricultural productivity,
besides being an important source of rural non-agricultural employment.
(3) Reduced transfers to state governments which have been facing a
major financial crunch and have therefore been forced to cut back their
own spending, particularly on social expenditure such as on education and
on health and sanitation, which had provided an important source of public
employment over the 1980s.
(4) Reduced spread and rising prices of the public distribution
system for food.
(5) Financial liberalisation measures which effectively reduced the
availability of rural credit.
Thus, in the 1990s, several of the public policies which
contributed to more employment and less poverty in the rural areas in the
earlier decade have been reversed. It should, therefore, not be entirely
surprising that rural non-agricultural employment appears to have declined
fairly sharply as soon as these policies began to be put into place from
1991 onwards.
There is a natural question of whether this increase in
agricultural employment was a positive development or a distress outcome
related to lower rural non-agricultural opportunities and higher poverty.
Those supporting the market-based reforms have argued that export
orientation and increased prices of cash crops have operated as incentives
for more output and investment in agriculture, and this has in turn meant
more agricultural employment as well.
In fact, however, the rate of growth of agricultural output has
slowed down after the reforms, rather than increase. This suggests
that the growth of labour demand in agriculture is likely to have
decelerated as well, especially given the known fact of declining
employment elasticities in cultivation. Consequently what is being
observed is almost certainly a rise in labour supply into the
agricultural sector from certain segments of the rural population,
particularly casual labourers and subsidiary workers.
This in itself suggests that the higher growth of agricultural
employment in the 1990s was driven more by distress factors, specifically
the lack of productive employment opportunities elsewhere in the rural
economy.
The shift to agriculture in the 1990s also fits in with the
hypothesis that the observed large increase in rural poverty following the
reforms was caused primarily by the factors which caused rural
non-agricultural employment to decline. This is also supported by changes
in the nature of employment, that is whether it was regular, casual or
self-employment.
Charts 5 and 6 present these data for men and women workers
respectively. Over the entire period from 1977-78 to 1998, there appears
to be a continuous trend of increase in casual contracts in employment,
mostly at the expense of regular employment. This tendency is sharpest in
the case of male workers over the 1990s. Thus, while casual work as a
proportion of all work increased from 27 per cent in 1977-78 to 31 per
cent in 1990-91 (an increase of 4 percentage points over 14 years) it had
increased again to nearly 38 per cent by 1998 (an increase of 7 per cent
in 7 years). The decline in male regular employment has been very sharp,
but even self-employment appears to have declined as a proportion of all
work.
For women workers, by contrast, the increase in casual work (from
35 per cent in 1977-78 to 41 per cent in 1990-91 to 44 per cent in 1998)
has been largely at the expense of self-employment. This has declined
particularly over the 1990s, from 60 per cent in 1992 to 53 per cent in
1998.
Data on unemployment are notoriously poor indicators in rural
India, for a number of reasons. Firstly, it should be borne in mind that
open unemployment is usually not an option for poor people, who have to
force themselves into some activity, however low-paying, so that changes
in open unemployment rates are not necessarily very good indicators of
changes in levels of economic activity. This is one reason for the
relatively low and stable nature of the unemployment rates reported by
both the NSS and the Census over time. Effectively these incorporate
possibly high and varying rates of disguised unemployment.
Secondly, as mentioned earlier, the continued under-reporting of
much household-based labour contributes to wrong assessments of the extent
of female economic activity in particular. Finally, there is the point
mentioned above, that the small samples may not be able to capture changes
in this variable simply because the rates are relatively low in the size
of the total population.
With these caveats in mind, Charts 7 and 8 present the data on open
unemployment rates for men and women in rural
India since
1993-94. While the male rates are close to the norm for the period since
the 1970s, the female rates are much higher than before, and show that the
decline in female work participation observed from Chart 2 is related not
to women's movement away from the labour force, but the sheer absence of
available employment opportunities.
The overall picture, then, is one of a relative decline in
productive employment opportunities, especially in non-agriculture, and
the growth of less attractive casual work for both men and women in rural
India over the 1990s. This corresponds with the observed persistence and
even increase in the ratio of people below the poverty line that has
already become the focus of much concern. It is clear that the
macro-economic policies of the 1990s have played an important role in both
of these processes.
|