There
is a paradox at the heart of political economy, which can be seen
as follows. Suppose a capitalist economy is saddled with substantial
unemployment and unutilized productive capacity, as is the case now
over the entire capitalist world. Suppose in this situation the State
increases its expenditure by enlarging its fiscal deficit, i.e. it
spends, let us say, Rs.100 more without any increase in its tax revenue.
And let us assume for simplicity that the capitalist economy is a
closed, isolated one. Then the Rs.100 of expenditure will directly
and indirectly, i.e. via the various rounds of further expenditure
it generates, increase aggregate demand, and hence employment, and
output in the economy (since no demand will be leaking out in the
form of larger imports from elsewhere because of the closed economy
assumption). This increase in output will of course increase profits
as well. The paradox then consists in this: if a rise in fiscal deficit
increases capitalists' profits, then why are they so opposed to fiscal
deficits? Why do they keep harping on ''fiscal responsibility'', the
financial capitalists most vocally, but the others too, though with
lesser stridency?
It may be thought at first sight that the problem arises because we
do not have closed capitalist economies, and that an increase in the
fiscal deficit will leak out in the form of larger import demand,
which will generate little additional employment at home but create
a balance of payments problem. But, the capitalists' opposition to
fiscal deficit arises not only in countries whose products are uncompetitive
and whose additional demand therefore leaks out abroad in the form
of larger imports; it arises even in strongly competitive economies,
where recession could be overcome, and more profits generated, through
a larger fiscal deficit, but where the capitalists' opposition prevents
this from happening. This opposition therefore is more fundamental
than merely the fear of a worsening of the balance of payments, which
brings us back to the question: why do capitalists oppose fiscal deficits?
The typical answer given to this question is that fiscal deficits
are simply bad policy, and the opposition of capitalists to them is
because of this fact and has nothing to do with their self-interest.
Just as a family cannot have a perpetual excess of expenditure over
its income, without at some point ceasing to be creditworthy, likewise
a government cannot keep having a perpetual fiscal deficit. By doing
so it gets saddled with mounting debt, which is bad per se since it
can never hope to pay back its debt, and which, for that very reason,
undermines its creditworthiness beyond a certain limit.
This, however, is a completely wrong answer, since the analogy between
the family and the government is a false analogy. To start with, if
the government uses the fiscal deficit to make investments in productive
assets, then it is doing something that is in principle no different
from what corporations do: corporations after all have always a backlog
of debt but still keep borrowing for making fresh investments. But
even if it is the case that the fiscal deficit is used to finance
expenditure other than investment expenditure, or that government
investment, unlike that of corporations, is not necessarily profit-making
(out of which interest payments could be made), the government still
stands on a very different footing from any other entity in the economy,
for two obvious reasons.
One, it has the power to tax, including even those from whom it borrows
to finance the fiscal deficit. Indeed the lesser is the leakage of
demand out of the economy, and the more the fiscal deficit generates
employment and output inside the economy, the greater is the borrowing
from within the economy, and hence the government's capacity to tax
the lenders. Two, since the government can always take recourse to
borrowing from the central bank, which can print money to meet its
borrowing requirements, the question of the government's losing its
creditworthiness simply does not arise.
True, if the central bank is made ''autonomous'' as a result of ''financial
liberalization'', and therefore ceases to be obliged to lend to the
government what it asks for, then the government loses this privilege.
But since the argument for making it ''autonomous'' is precisely to
prevent the government from going on borrowing from it, such prevention
must have some independent rationale. For exploring this independent
rationale for preventing a perennial fiscal deficit, we must therefore
deliberately preclude financial liberalization.
It may also be thought that running a perennial fiscal deficit of
this sort, which is financed by borrowing from the central bank, would
entail the emergence of inflationary pressures; but we are talking
about the economy being in the midst of unemployment and unutilized
capacity, where the need is for increasing, and not curtailing, aggregate
demand. To be sure, the government should not run a fiscal deficit
if the economy is producing close to full capacity output, for that
may cause inflation; but why should there be any objection to its
doing so when the economy is mired in recession?
The objection to a fiscal deficit (at least beyond a certain minuscule
level relative to the gross domestic product) implies de facto an
objection to larger public expenditure that boosts the level of aggregate
demand. Since such larger public expenditure, if not financed through
a fiscal deficit, would have to be financed through larger tax revenue,
of which the capitalists would normally be called upon to provide
a part, their opposition to fiscal deficits merges with their opposition
to larger government expenditure: the two become indistinguishable.
The question we again come back to is: why this opposition?
Economists, especially Marxist economists who have attempted to go
deep into the political economy of the system, have for long been
intrigued by this paradox and have answered it in a variety of ways.
And all of them have noted that the opposition of capitalists is never
to all forms of public expenditure, but only to some. Public expenditure
in the form of ''transfer payments'' to the poor and working people,
even though the spending out of such transfers has the effect of increasing
output and capitalists' profits, is opposed by the latter because
it increases the bargaining power of the workers. Likewise public
expenditure in specific spheres, even when it increases aggregate
demand and profits, tends to compete with private interests in those
spheres in which it is undertaken. Thus larger government expenditure
in building hospitals has the effect of making private hospitals less
profitable by exposing them to public competition; larger government
housing construction has the effect of reducing the profitability
of private house-builders; and so on. Capitalists' opposition to public
expenditure however gets muted if such expenditure is undertaken neither
in the form of transfer payments nor in spheres where there is such
competition. And one obvious sphere that satisfies both these requirements
is military expenditure, which explains, according to Baran and Sweezy,
why post-war capitalism relied upon larger U.S. military expenditure
to keep up its level of aggregate demand.
But the opposition of big capital, especially financial interests,
to public expenditure cannot just be explained by these factors alone.
There are more fundamental objections, which also explain why, in
the midst of the current recession, the right-wing demand in the United
States is not so much for a step up in military expenditure (which
could be made to appear plausible given the fact that the US is at
present engaged in two wars), but for a cutback in public expenditure
together with tax concessions to the super-rich. What explains such
policy advocacy in the midst of the recession?
This brings us to the crux of the problem. The fundamental property
of a capitalist system is that its level of output and employment
is determined essentially by the so-called ''state of confidence''
of the capitalists. When they feel ''confident'', they invest; and
this raises the level of aggregate demand, and hence output and employment.
When they do not feel ''confident'', the opposite happens. To be sure,
this does not mean that the functioning of a capitalist economy is
purely a matter of psychology. Undoubtedly, the capitalists' outlook
is governed by what their actual experience has been, i.e. how certain
objective indicators have behaved (e.g. whether sales have been increasing).
But how this experience is interpreted and gets translated into investment
decisions depends also upon the state of ''confidence'' of the capitalists.
Indeed this fact is what gives the capitalists an upper hand. If employment
has to increase, then, within the logic of the system, the State must
take steps to improve the ''confidence'' of the capitalists. If on
the other hand the State directly tries to increase employment through
its own expenditure, then that makes the ''state of confidence'' of
the capitalists irrelevant, and hence amounts implicitly to undermining
the logic of the system and the role of capitalists within it. This
is why all public expenditure that directly serves the interests of
the capitalists, for instance investment subsidies, guaranteed rates
of return, input subsidies, making land available at throwaway prices,
are welcomed by the capitalists, as are tax-cuts in their favour.
But all public expenditure that by-passes capitalists and directly
generates employment is opposed by them (with the exception of military
expenditure).
Consider just two examples. The Cameron government in Britain, which
never tires of preaching the virtues of ''austerity'' and has imposed
drastic ''austerity'' measures, has recently announced a programme
of subsidizing capitalists' investment in infrastructure from the
budget; but the capitalist press that systematically hails ''austerity''
has not complained about this programme! Likewise in the United States,
when the right-wing and the corporate media were opposing a continuation
of Obama's meagre $700 billion stimulus package, as much as $13 trillion
was being made available under various heads for bailing out the financial
system that was engulfed in crisis because of the collapse of the
housing ''bubble''. But the big corporate and financial interests
were only too happy with the latter expenditure!
This also explains the fate of Keynesianism. Keynes was worried that
if unemployment continued at high levels, then capitalism would succumb
to the socialist challenge. So keen was he to preserve capitalism
that he advocated public expenditure as a means of directly combating
unemployment, and not indirectly by boosting the ''state of confidence''
of the capitalists. For this unpardonable sin, however, even Keynes,
notwithstanding the fact that he was trying to protect capitalism,
is shunned by capitalists today.
A barometer of the ''state of confidence'' of the capitalists is the
stock market, which in turn reflects the ''state of confidence'' of
the financial speculators. Finance capital therefore is particularly
concerned that the ''revival of the state of confidence'' route, which
is so advantageous to itself, for generating employment, must not
get by-passed. The fact that finance capital is particularly insistent
upon ''sound finance'', i.e. eschewing fiscal deficits, can be explained
by this.
*
This article was originally published in the ''People's Democracy''
on 5 July 2012.