India's
balance of payments position provides the principal source of comfort for
India's policy makers. Large inflows of invisibles in 2001-02 ensured a
small current account surplus after many years, so that the large inflows
of deposits, debt and investment contributed in the net to an accumulation
of reserves that have in recent times touched a record level of $60
billion. While remittance, debt and investment flows have played an
important role here, there is one other factor that has contributed to
create these conditions. This is the fact that barring the 2 years 1998-99
and 1999-2000, India's trade deficit has been close to or well below the
levels it reached at the end of the 1980s.
As Chart 1 shows, the trade deficit which was close to $6000 million in
1990-91, came down substantially during the immediate post-reform years
till 1993-94, rose subseqently to around $6500 million in 1997-98, shot up
to $9170 million and $12848 million in 1998-99 and 1999-2000, and then
fell to the $6000-6600 range in 2000-01 and 2001-02.
This experience with the deficit during the 1990s can be broken up into
four periods of varying duration. First, during the years 1991-92 to
1995-96, both exports and imports grew at more or less similar rates, so
that the deficit remained low in most years and fluctuated within the $1
billion to $5 billion range. Second, between 1995-96 and 1998-99, while
imports continued to grow, exports stagnated resulting in a widening of
the trade deficit to $9.1 billion by the end of that period. Third, in
1999-00, while exports recovered, imports surged because of a rise in oil
prices, resulting in the widening of the trade deficit to $12.8 billion.
Finally, in 2000-01 and 2001-02, while exports rose initially and then
remained at that level, imports stagnated and the trade deficit returned
to the levels it had touched in the mid-1990s.
One feature of this experience is the sharp deceleration in export growth
since 1995-96. While over the six-year period 1989-90 to 1995-96 exports
rose by 91 per cent, the increase over the subsequent six years ending in
2001-02 was only 38 per cent. Further, besides some expansion in earning
from exports of software and IT-enabled services, the structure of India's
exports has not changed very much. Clearly, the dynamism that was expected
on the export front in the wake of reform has not been realised. This
implies that whatever "gains" have been registered on the trade front has
been on account of the containment of imports, which is indeed puzzling
given the expected consequences of import liberalisation.
Resolving this puzzle requires a closer look at the performance of
different categories of imports. It is known that movements in oil
imports, which are influenced by oil prices, have substantially influenced
the size and direction of India's overall import bill. Chart 2 examines,
therefore, the movements in India's non-oil trade balance. The picture
that emerges is indeed remarkable. During the period 1990-91 to 2000-01,
in all years excepting one (1998-99), India's non-oil trade has either
been in balance or reflected a surplus of exports over imports. Further, a
rise in exports in 2000-01 and a fall in imports had taken that surplus to
$7.8 billion. This is remarkable because, barring a couple of years,
India's export growth has not been creditable. On the other hand, import
liberalisation, involving the removal of quantitative restrictions and
reductions in tariffs, was expected to result in a surge in non-oil
imports. It is clearly because such a surge has not occurred that India's
trade deficit has been contained in most years when oil prices were not
ruling high.
However, Chart 3, which traces the category-wise movements in imports,
suggests that it may be premature to arrive at such a judgement. Movements
have been quite varied in the 4 principal categories of imports (oil,
non-oil bulk, export-related and other imports). While oil imports have
fluctuated quite significantly, as is to be expected, and rose to
relatively high levels in 1996-97 and 1999-00 to 2000-01, export related
imports have shown a low but consistent rate of increase since 1994-95.
Non-oil bulk imports on the other hand have stagnated till the mid-1990s,
risen by a small amount during 1995-97 and stagnated once again
thereafter. The really striking feature of the experience described by
Chart 3 is the increase in "other imports" between 1991-92 and 1998-99,
after which they have stagnated. We must note here, that the segment of
imports most affected by liberalisation was the large category of "other
imports", which includes most manufactured imports directed towards
production for or direct sale in the domestic market. The share of that
category, which stood at 40 per cent in 1990-91, rose to 47 per cent in
1995-96 and 52 per cent in 1998-99, before falling to 43 per cent in
2000-01 (Chart 4).
The point to note is that this increase was not of a magnitude adequate to
undermine the gains in terms of import containment registered in other
areas. From Chart 4, which presents the shares of different categories of
imports in the total, it is clear that while the share of oil imports has
fluctuated significantly, rising sharply in periods when the trade deficit
has widened, the share of export related imports has varied within a small
range and stagnated over time, and that of non-oil bulk imports has
declined. This has meant that the rise in the share of other imports did
not result in a worsening of the trade deficit to an unsustainable extent.
One reason why the other imports category did not rise even further as a
result of the liberalisation was the fact that capital goods imports which
rose from $4.2 billion in 1991-92 to $10.3 billion in 1995-96, stagnated
thereafter, fluctuating between $9 and $10 billion till 1998-99 (Chart 5).
This was the period when after a short-term boom between 1993-94 and
1995-96, Indian industry registered a deceleration in its rate of
expansion. That this deceleration would have affected capital goods
imports through its impact on investment is partly corroborated by the
fact that after 1998-99, when industry began its slide into
near-recessionary conditions, capital goods imports fell below $9 billion
in 1999-00 touching $8.8 billion in 2000-01. Since capital goods
constitute an important component of other imports, though its share fell
from 60.4 per cent in 1995-96 to 40.4 per cent in 2000-01 (Chart 6), this
trend would have substantially influenced movements in the 'other imports'
category.
Has any fact other than demand played a role in influencing the demand for
imported capital goods? Chart 7, would suggest that prices have played a
role as well. Over a 13-year period starting from 1980-81, the unit value
and quantum indices of imports of Machinery and Transport Equipment
maintained a consistent rise. However, in 1994-95, the unit value index,
representing the price of capital goods, dropped significantly, only to
rise sharply over the next four years till 1998-99, and fall marginally
thereafter. Interestingly the quantum index of imports of Machinery and
Transport Equipment shot up in 1994-95 and then fell sharply till 1997-98,
before stabilising at that level over the next three years.
These movements seem to suggest that the demand for capital goods imports
is highly price elastic in nature. However, some caution is called for in
arriving at that conclusion. To start with, Machinery and Transport
Equipment is an extremely heterogenous category, comprising of an
extremely wide range of entities. Further, the structural changes in
industrial production in the wake of liberalisation have resulted in
substantial changes in the composition, quality and import-intensiveness
of industrial output and therefore in the nature of its demand for
imported capital goods and components. Movements in import unit values may
reflect changes in the composition and quality of commodities being
imported rather than changes in prices of a given set of commodities. This
implies that changes in the quantum of imports cannot be attributed
directly to prices.
Secondly, one consequence of liberalisation has been an increase in the
production of a range of "new" import-intensive manufactures based on
component imports by production facilities that carry out assembly or
penultimate stage production activities. A crucial requirement for these
units is the adequate availability of imported intermediates and
components to meet demands for the final product. Thus it is not merely an
increase in demand for the final product that triggers an increase in
imports, but expectations of any increase in demand, since firms should be
in a position to ensure delivery in short periods of time and not be
strapped by delays created by import procurement.
This would imply that in periods of rising demand, firms would accumulate
inventories of imported components and intermediates. Given the fact that
components and spares for capital are included in the "capital goods"
category in import data, periods of such accumulation of inventories would
also be periods in which the imports of "capital goods" would register an
increase. The years 1994-95 to 1996-97 were years when as a result of the
release of the pent-up demand for import-intensive manufactured goods,
there was a "min-boom" in industry, which would have resulted in a sharp
increase in capital goods in the forms of components of various kinds. In
fact, qualitative evidence suggests that there was not just such an
increase, but that the expectations created by the mini-boom resulted in
the excess accumulation of such inventories, which firms were hard put to
reduce once the market created by a pre-existing pent-up demand was
exhausted. Thus the quantum indices of capital goods provided in Chart 7,
which point to a sharp increase in imports in 1994-95, reflect in all
probability this tendency rather than the effects of a decline in prices.
It is also not surprising, therefore, that once inventories were
accumulated and demand for the final good tapered off, such imports fell
sharply and stabilised at a low level. The recession rather than price has
finally put restraints on the run-away increase in imports of 'capital
goods'.
That this could be a valid explanation is suggested by the experience with
Chemicals, were as Chart 8 shows, both unit value indices and prices have
risen for most years during the 1990s. While the experience in 1989-90,
1995-96 and 2000-01 suggests that the import demand for chemicals is
indeed price sensitive, price changes are hardly the explanation for
trends in imports, which must come from the demand side.
Import
prices could, however, have had an effect on import trends in other
commodities, which do not share these characteristics of capital goods or
chemical imports. One such group of commodities is Food and Food Articles.
As Chart 9 shows, the unit value index of Food and Food Articles rose
significantly between 1990-91 and 1994-95, fell sharply thereafter till
1999-00 and rose in 2000-01. The quantum of imports on the other hand,
fluctuated around a stagnant trend during the first of these periods, rose
sharply between 1995-96 and 1998-99 and has fallen quite significantly
over the next two years. The price elasticity of demand has possibly
played a role here ensuring that imports rose only when prices were low
and fell in response to price increases so as to keep prices in control.
The reason why the price factor has been so important here is that
"sticky" imports, which occur irrespective of the price level, are no more
a major component of food imports.
These "sticky" imports are primarily those made by official agencies to
counter domestic shortages and the inflation they engender. Two factors
have contributed to a decline in the share of such imports. First, a
combination of consecutive normal or good monsoons and a slow growth in
demand that has substantially eased the availability of many food items,
especially foodgrains, reducing the need for imports to meet shortfalls.
Second, the fact that import liberalisation has contributed to the
dampening of upward movements in domestic food prices over the long run,
reducing the need for anti-inflationary imports.
To sum up, despite liberalisation and the stagnation or slow growth of
India's exports since the mid-1990s, India's balance of trade deficit has
not worsened because of the sluggishness of aggregate import growth in
years when oil prices have been subdued. Two factors seem to have combined
to deliver this result. First, the observed price elasticity of demand for
imported food and food articles, which keeps the import bill on this
account under control. Second, the sluggishness in the economy in general
and the industrial sector in particular after 1995-96, which has resulted
in a tapering off and even decline in the demand for a range of
manufactured intermediates. This has meant that the trade deficit tends to
widen significantly only when oil prices rise, since the demand for oil
and oil products is substantially price inelastic.
Thus there appear to be only two circumstances that can lead to a
substantial rise in the import bill. First, a recovery and sustained
growth in industrial production. And second, a sharp rise in oil prices.
If either of these occurs, the trade deficit is bound to widen, unless
India is able to make the breakthrough in world markets that the
liberalisation was expected to deliver and has not.
In the meanwhile, a contained deficit, combined with large inflows of
remittances, deposits, debt and investment have created a situation where
India's foreign exchange reserves have increased substantially to touch
the record levels at which they stand at present.