An
end-July meeting of trade officials of the WTO's 142 member nations at
Geneva, laid bare the constraints to the efforts of those pushing for
the launch of a new, ninth round of international trade talks at the
Ministerial Meeting scheduled for November at Doha, Qatar. Heading the
drive for a new round is the US, which would like to see further
reduction in barriers to its exports of industrial goods as well as more
progress in the ongoing negotiations on freeing trade in agriculture and
services. Any acceleration on trade liberalisation on these fronts it
feels can only be achieved by incorporating negotiations on these
matters into a new round of talks that cannot but end with agreement on
freer trade.
Needless to say, few are convinced by the US' proclaimed commitment to
free trade. Not only does it continue to support its agricultural sector
with huge transfers that fall outside the scope of the definition of
subsidies under the Uruguay Round's Agreement on Agriculture (AoA), but
it has buckled under domestic political pressure to provide virtually no
concessions to developing country exports of textiles and has
unwarrantedly used “anti-dumping” levies to protect domestic producers
of commodities like steel, against competition from developing country
exporters. The net effect is that movements in world trade are not in
keeping with the expectations of the developing countries. Although
world trade as a whole as grown much faster that world GDP (Chart 1),
this is more true of manufacturing trade and production than of
agriculture (Charts 2 & 3). Hence, benefits to developing countries, if
any, have been concentrated among the few who are major exporters of
non-traditional manufactures.
It was the US which initiated in the 1980s the process of substituting
measures of support that directly impinge on agricultural prices with
income support measures, which are ostensibly “decoupled” from prices.
One example of such decoupled support is
"deficiency
payments" made to farmers when actual prices
rule below target prices. Since these payments, which are linked to
specific crops and to farm area, allow farmers to remain in production
despite incurring higher costs, they do affect the level of production
and therefore must influence prices and trade. Yet the Uruguay Round
Agreement excluded these payments from the list of subsidies that
distort trade.
The lead provided by the US was followed by the European Union, which
made the shift from price to income support the principal plank of the
reform of its Common Agricultural Policy. Not surprisingly, these two
powerful forces came together and ensured that these types of support to
agriculture, categorised as “green box subsidies”, were excluded from
computing the Aggregate Measure of Support (AMS), which nations were
committed to reduce under the AoA, on the grounds that they were not
trade-distorting. What is more, under the Peace Clause included in the
AoA, no disputes could be raised regarding the "green-box
policies" and other AoA conforming support and
subsidy measures, during the phase when the agreement was being
implemented.
The OECD, however, periodically computes the total subsidies provided to
agriculture by its member countries, which it terms “producer subsidy
equivalent”. In practice, while AMS commitments have been met, the PSE
has remained at extremely high levels. To quote the WTO: "In
1999, the OECD estimated total support to agriculture at f306 billion,
up 5.6% over 1998, a rise explained by ‘low world commodity prices, and
the resulting pressure they put on farm incomes, [which] led many OECD
countries to introduce new measures or to provide additional support to
farmers'. Producer support granted in the area was estimated at f236.7
billion, of which the largest single share is accounted for by the
European Union (45%), followed by Japan (23%) and the United States
(21%); it should be noted that the OECD figures do not segregate less
from more distorting measures of support, notably support in the 18
"green box"
categories of Annex 2 of the Agreement on Agriculture. The OECD notes
that producer support levels have risen to match previous highs
established a decade ago, when the Uruguay Round was under way."
What is more, prior to 1986-88, which was taken as the base period for
the benchmark figure in the Uruguay Round from which duty reductions had
to be implemented, the US and other developed countries had
substantially raised the support they provided to agriculture, making
the base value extremely high. Thus, the producer subsidy equivalent in
the US is estimated to have risen from 8 per cent of the value of
agricultural production in 1979 to 45 per cent in 1986, and from 45 to
66 per cent in the EC (10). The net result of such protection has been
an extremely slow growth of world agricultural trade during the 1990s
(Chart 4).
As mentioned earlier, it was not only in agriculture that the US
resorts to protection under the veneer of being a votary of free trade.
For example, from the point of view of the developing countries, the
most visible and "multilaterally" accepted non-tariff barrier
arrangement is the Multi-Fibre Arrangement. That arrangement was the
end-result of a series of negotiated agreements starting in the 1960s,
all of which sought to provide the developed countries with the time
needed to restructure their industries so that competitive textile
exports from lower-cost developing countries do not "disrupt" their
markets. Despite three decades of agreement on that principle and
periodic revisions of the deadline for ending import restrictions,
textiles still are not permitted free entry in developed-country
markets. The case for an immediate end to such restrictions, under a new
multilateral trade regime was therefore strong. However, though the
Uruguay Round agreement on textiles and clothing provided for the
phasing out of restraints stemming from the Multi-fibre Arrangement, it
once again delayed the process of liberalisation. The process that was
to occur in four stages over a ten-year period starting 1995 was heavily
"back-loaded", in the sense that most of the liberalisation was to occur
during the last stages. The four stages defined involved the following:
-
In the first stage, beginning on the date on which the
Uruguay Round became effective, each signatory nation was required to
remove quotas only on products that account for 16 per cent of its
total volume of imports of four categories of textiles and clothing in
1990 (tops and yarns, fabrics, made-up textiles products and
clothing);
-
In the second stage, beginning three years and one
month after the agreement enters into force, quotas are to be removed
on a further 17 per cent of the total volume of 1990 imports;
-
In the third stage, which begins four years later,
quotas are to be removed on products that account for not less than 18
per cent of the total volume of 1990 imports;
-
Finally, after 10
years and one month, all other quota restrictions on imports
accounting for 49 per cent of the total are to be eliminated.
This
prolonged and back-loaded agreement in a labour-intensive area in which
the developed countries had agreed to open up markets four decades back,
points both to the relative positions of power of developed and
developing countries in the Uruguay Round negotiations as well as to the
extent of commitment of the latter to offer greater market access as a
quid pro quo for the rapid liberalisation of trade and investment
rules in the developing countries. The developed countries have
exploited the back-loaded schedule, by liberalising in the initial
phases textile products that do not appear in the export basket of the
developing countries. As a result even after six years of the start of
implementation of the Uruguay Round, the access of developing country
textile exporters to developed country markets remains restricted. As
Chart 5 shows, the growth of textile exports has collapsed during the
1990s, as compared with the second half of the 1980s. Further, there has
been little change in the distribution of textile and clothing exports
between major regions (Charts 6 and 7).
Protectionism in the industrial area has not been restricted to
textiles. Over the last few years the US has been using the option of
introducing “anti-dumping” levies to prevent import surges or market
disruption as a protectionist device against manufactured imports from
the developing countries. The most blatant example is that of steel,
where industry and union pressure led to the introduction of levies that
violate WTO norms. Not surprisingly, the WTO's dispute settlement panel
has already ruled against the US in cases filed by some countries, and
is expected to do the same in others, including one filed by India.
These
developments have deprived most developing countries of even the limited
benefits they were to get from the Uruguay Round, and made them
suspicious of claims that a new round would bring further gains. Not
surprisingly, they are demanding something in return for their own
liberalisation efforts, which have substantially increased the access of
developed-country producers and investors to their markets. This makes a
review of the implementation of the Uruguay Round agreement, and a
revision of that agreement to accommodate developing country interests,
their principal concern.
Of all the Uruguay Round agreements, the
TRIPS agreement is possibly the one in greatest need of revision. The
TRIPS Agreement protects intellectual property rights in all WTO member
countries and constrains the production of imitation products. It is
estimated that the number of patents granted worldwide in 1995 was about
710,000 and that at the end of 1995 about 3.7 million patents were in
force in the world. Since then, there has been an increase in patenting
activity, dominantly by large companies based in the North. Thus, it has
been estimated that industrial countries hold 97 per cent of all
patents, and that 90 per cent of all technology and product patents are
held by MNCs. Privately, negotiators acknowledge that the TRIPS
Agreement was to a great extent driven by MNC interests rather than the
requirements of citizens across the world. The developing country case
for revision has many grounds:
-
It has been stressed
by the representatives of several developing countries in the WTO that
the objective of fostering the transfer and dissemination of
technology, which is already explicitly stated in Article 7 of the
TRIPS Agreement, should be made operational through special
provisions. This is because, after a period in the early 1990s when
technology access constraints were relaxed somewhat, there has been a
tightening up after TRIPS was signed. Also, the stronger protection to
invention which has been granted under TRIPS makes it more difficult
for industries in developing countries to adapt and use, through
reverse engineering and other devices, developed elsewhere. This
reduces one of the more obvious means of "catching up" by late
industrialisers, and closes one of the more important sources of
technology particularly for small and medium enterprises across the
world.
-
Much technological
progress in the recent past has been in the field of biotechnology and
genetic engineering, which in turn has been based on generic resources
which are often available only in the tropics (that is, mainly
developing countries). Increasingly, while research organised by
private corporations into genetic resources has drawn on the
traditional knowledge of indigenous communities, these communities and
peoples themselves do not benefit from the patents or even from the
resulting inventions. Reconciling the TRIPS agreement with the
Convention on Biological Diversity and accommodating "farmers'
rights", defined by the FAO as the "rights arising from the past,
present and future contribution of farmers in conserving, improving
and making available plant genetic resources" must become one of the
focal points of renegotiation.
-
Article 27.3 (b) of TRIPS says that members may also
exclude from patentability plants and animals other than
micro-organisms, and essentially biological processes for the
production of plants and animals other than non-biological and
micro-biological processes. However, members shall provide for the
protection of plant varieties either by patents or an effective sui
generis system or by any combination thereof. These provisions were to
be reviewed after four years, but no systematic review has been put
into place at the WTO. In this context, a recent proposal of the
African Group of WTO members is significant, as it questions the TRIPS
Agreement's requirement for mandatory patenting of some life forms and
some natural processes. It calls for a clarification that plants,
animals and micro-organisms should not be patentable, and that natural
processes that produce plants, animals and other living organisms
should also not be patentable. The paper also puts forward the view
that by stipulating compulsory patenting of micro-organisms (which are
natural living things) and micro-biological processes (which are
natural processes), Article 27.3(b) contravenes the basic tenets of
patent laws: that substances and processes that exist in nature are a
discovery and not an invention and thus are not patentable. The
African countries have thus proposed a review of TRIPS which would :
(a) clarify that developing countries can opt for a national sui
generis law that protects innovations of indigenous and local farming
communities; (b) allow the continuation of traditional farming
practices, including the right to save and exchange seeds and sell
their harvests; (c) prevent anti-competitive rights or practices that
threatens food sovereignty of people in developing countries; (d)
harmonise Article 27.3(b) with the provisions of the CBD and the FAO's
International Undertaking, which take into account the conservation
and sustainable use of biological diversity, the protection of the
rights and knowledge of indigenous and local communities, and the
promotion of farmers rights. These proposals have been supported by
many other developing countries.
It has
also been pointed out that the implementation of public health policies
may be restrained by the implementation of TRIPS. It forces all
countries rich and poor to adopt the same, strict guidelines on
respecting corporate patents, trademarks and copyrights. The TRIPS
guarantees monopoly ownership over, among other things, pharmaceutical
patents; thus a WTO member may not be able to suspend intellectual
property rights even to address critical public health issues. Once an
approach focused on public health is accepted, several articles may
require revision, for instance, Article 27.1 in order to exclude the
patentability of "essential medicines" listed by WHO; Article 30 so as
to incorporate an explicit recognition of an "early working" exception
for the approval of generic products before the expiration of a patent;
and, Article 31 in order to clarify the right to grant and the scope of
compulsory licenses for public health reasons. One of the most important
areas of public concern relates to the availability and prices of
life-saving drugs. The move from process patents to product patents
dramatically reduces the ability of companies in developing countries to
produce cheaper versions of important life-saving drugs, especially
those relating to cancer and HIV/AIDS. The extent to which this can make
a difference is apparent in the very wide differences in drug prices
that can be observed in India, where product patents are were not in
force and other developing countries in Asia where such patents were
allowed in the 1990s.
These concerns of the developing countries would be completely ignored
if the US drive for a new round of trade negotiations is accepted.
Unfortunately, the US is supported by the Cairns group of agricultural
exporters, which includes Australia and Argentina, which wants a
substantial reduction in barriers to trade in agricultural goods. This
has made the EU, supported by Japan, which want to maintain the
protection afforded to their agricultural sectors, the real stumbling
block at the top.
As a filibustering measure, the EU and Japan have decided to bring in
other issues into the picture. The new round, they argue, should be a
comprehensive one that includes issues such as multilateral investment
rules, competition policy and the environment. An earlier effort to push
through a multilateral agreement on investment, that sought to tie the
hand of nations when dealing with foreign investors investing in their
soil, had led to such an acrimonious debate that it had to be shelved.
Advocating the inclusion of investment as one of the subjects that must
enter the agenda for a new round, is to rake up an issue that could
prove controversial.
A similar controversial issue is the environment, with the focus of
attention now on genetically modified (GM) foods. Partly under pressure
from consumers, the EU has come up with proposals for labelling of GM
foods. The proposals would introduce a system for tracing genetically
modified organisms (GMOs) from the farm to the supermarket; a
requirement to label all foods derived from GM ingredients; and a 1 per
cent limit on the amount of GM material that finds its way accidentally
into food or feed. This has already angered American farmers who
currently grow GM foods like corn varieties, which are currently not
authorised in the EU. Others, like the Cairns group countries are
worried about the impact this can have on agricultural trade in the
future. And developing countries as a group are concerned that the
environment issue is being raised by the EU as a means of using
environmental regulations as protectionist devices.
Despite these divisions, there is growing optimism that a deal can be
struck between the EU and the US brokered by two friends, Pascal Lamy,
the EU trade commissioner, and Robert Zoellick, the US trade
representative, who are working overtime to convince the governments
they represent that concessions leading to agreement are a must. In
their effort they are being backed by arguments that a new round is the
best medicine to combat the recession that looms large over the
developed world. Even the “narrow agenda” being advocated by the US
would deliver hugely positive results argue some. One study by Drusilla
Brown of Tufts University and Alan Deardorff and Robert Stern of the
University of Michigan estimates that a reduction in tariffs on
agricultural and industrial products and services by 33% would deliver a
one-off increase in global welfare of over $600 billion, as compared
with a $75 billion increase garnered from the Uruguay Round.
Developing countries are unlikely to be taken in by such rosy estimates
of the welfare benefits of a new round. A GATT study (1994) estimated
that merchandise exports of developing countries will increase by about
37 per cent in real terms after the Uruguay Round benefits are fully
phased in. This figure was much higher than that for developed countries
and economic groupings such as the US (8.2 per cent) and the European
Union (7.8 per cent). Exports of developing countries of manufactured
goods amounted to $700 billion in 1992 and when estimated to grow at a
"normal" rate of 6 per cent per annum were expected to touch $1,500
billion by the year 2005. This implies that the Uruguay Round was
estimated to contribute to an additional increase in the manufactured
exports of developing countries of $560 billion (37 per cent of $1,500
billion). In addition, GATT estimated static and dynamic income gains of
$116 billion for developing countries from three sources: gains from the
reduction of tariffs on industrial goods ($33 billion); the elimination
of non-tariff barriers on industrial goods ($68 billion); and the
reduction of agricultural barriers ($14 billion). The most important
gains were expected from the elimination of industrial non-tariff
barriers, especially those of quotas under the Multi-fibre Arrangement.
Suffice it to say, current prognoses about trends in world trade are far
less optimistic. In fact, the evidence seems to indicate that developing
countries have been major losers. If the Brown, Deardorff, Stern study
quoted above is considered, even their optimistic methods estimate total
gains from the Uruguay Round at just $75 billion; given their uneven
distribution, this would make developing country gains, if any, well
short of the $116 billion promised by GATT in 1994.
This makes the position, taken by the "like-minded
group" of developing countries, led by India,
Pakistan, Egypt and Malaysia, that implementation issues and a review of
impact are crucial, extremely strong. But dissensions between the 142
members in general and the developing countries themselves in
particular, makes their case weak in practice, even if not in theory.
There are reportedly 30-40 members, including the US, which are willing
to go along with the EU on including investment in the agenda. This
provides a major weapon for working a compromise, even if at the expense
of the developing countries. And within the developing countries, there
are some who have reportedly expressed their willingness to divide
implementation issues into those that need to be addressed before a new
round and those that can be considered as part of the round. This could
help postpone discussion of the most controversial issues like textiles
and agricultural support.
Once the developing camp is divided, pressure exerted
by using mechanisms outside the terrain of the WTO can force developing
countries fall in line. This is precisely what happened in the Uruguay
Round, where the original negotiating position of countries like India
had little to do with what they settled for finally. It is therefore
ominous that the Financial Times reported that besides Brazil, Mexico
and South Africa, "that favour a round, as
does China, which is poised to enter the
WTO", "even
India, which has long led the opposition to new global negotiations,
seems to be wavering."
If this tendency is visible so early in the
negotiations, the likelihood is that the developing countries would be
forced to go along with any agreement on the agenda for a new round
thrashed out between the US, on the one hand, and the EU and Japan on
the other. If, therefore, any equity has to be introduced into the
system of world trade that is being institutionalised through repeated
trade negotiations, those joining the growing opposition to
globalisation within civil society must deliver it. No wonder, the G-10
has been forced to sit up and take note of this opposition, even if it
is with the aim of suppressing it.