The
Indian rupee stood at a robust Rs. 44.4 to the dollar at the beginning
of the second week of April. At that level the rupee had appreciated
by more than 13 percent vis-a-vis the dollar over the preceding 13 months
(Chart 1). This suggests that the Reserve Bank of India has not intervened
in the market and bought up surplus foreign exchange to the extent required
to relax the upward pressure on the value of the rupee and stall its
appreciation. This reluctance could partly be because, given the relatively
high level of already accumulated foreign exchange reserves, the central
bank is finding it difficult to match the surge in capital inflows with
new purchases.
The surge in capital inflows is explained largely by developments on
the supply side, with India being chosen as one of the favoured destinations
by financial investors seeking to exploit the cheap liquidity that developed
country governments have pumped into the system in response to the financial
crisis. Further, like many other emerging markets, India is becoming
a victim of the dollar carry trade, in which international players borrow
in dollar markets, where liquidity is ample and interest rates are low
because of anti-crisis measures, and invest in equity, debt and real
estate in emerging markets, where returns are much higher, in order
to profit from the differential between the cost of debt and the return
on investment. This is a game that seems to especially attract international
financial firms seeking to quickly recoup the losses they suffered in
the recent recession.
That this kind of game is currently popular with respect to India as
well is clear from the fact that the rupee's appreciation is associated
with a boom in equity markets driven largely by foreign institutional
investment, as a result of which the Sensex is courting the 18,000 level
once again. Balance of payments data recently released by the Reserve
Bank of India indicate that net portfolio investment inflow during April-December
2009 amounted to $23.6 billion, as compared with an outflow of 11.3
billion during the crisis months of April-December 2008 (Chart 2). The
accumulation of reserves during the April-December 2009 period amounted
to $31.5 billion. While valuation changes contributed to an increase
in dollar reserve figures, the importance of portfolio inflows and central
bank intervention in currency markets cannot be denied.
This process has since continued. According to figures from the Securities
and Exchange Board of India, as of April 11, net investments by FIIs
in debt and equity markets amounted to an additional $10.1 billion,
during 2010. Seen in this light, the reluctance of the RBI to intervene
adequately to absorb these inflows is understandable.
This
trend reflective of the dollar-carry trade feeds on itself for two reasons.
First, it is well known that despite post-liberalisation buoyancy the
Indian stock market is still both narrow and shallow. Narrow because
there are relatively few listed companies whose stocks are actively
traded. And shallow because the proportion of ''free-floating'' shares
in these companies not held by promoters and available for regular trading
is limited. As a result whenever there is even a minor surge in foreign
institutional investment flowing into these markets, the demand they
generate at the margin is enough to drive stock prices up quite quickly,
widening the differential between the cost of borrowing and the return
on investment and attracting further investments. This tends to generate
a self-reinforcing and often speculative spiral of investment.
Secondly, the expected return to the investor is even higher than this
differential because as and when she decides to sell financial assets
to book profits and repatriate capital to clear debts incurred at home,
the appreciation of the rupee yields more dollars than would have been
the case at the exchange rate when the investment was first made. This
provides an additional return that justifies even more the speculative
spiral and leads to further appreciation of the rupee.
The corollary of such rupee appreciation is of course a weakening of
India's export competitiveness because the dollar values of the country's
exports rise as the rupee appreciates. It is to prevent or moderate
that outcome that central banks have to manage the exchange rate through
open market operations, involving in this case the purchase of dollars
and an increase in reserves. But if this increase in the assets of the
central bank is not neutralised or sterilised through the sale of government
securities, for example, then money supply to the economy increases.
In the past the Reserve Bank of India had resorted to this option to
retain its control over the pace of expansion of money supply. But with
the inflow of capital having risen sharply and been quite high in most
years of this decade, its ability to do so depended on rebuilding its
depleted stock of government securities through special schemes like
the Market Stabilisation Scheme which create their own problems. So
the reluctance to intervene may be because of a decision to retain some
degree of control over the monetary lever ignoring (at least for some
time) the fall out for the rupee.
Whatever be the explanation for that reluctance, it is material only
because as of now dealing with the source of the problem, which is the
embarrassingly large and unneeded inflow of foreign capital for what
are speculative investments, is not an option for the government and
the central bank. Some other countries, like Brazil, have sought to
deal with the recent surge with measures, however limited, that are
directed at curbing speculative inflows. Since this would go against
the grain of the ideology influencing economic reform, which includes
the belief that maintaining a freer and more open capital account is
the best option, the Reserve Bank of India that wants control over the
monetary lever and is faced with a surge in capital inflows would have
to tolerate rupee appreciation.
But it is clear that the central bank cannot continue with this stance
for long. India's balance of payments statistics point to high and persisting
trade and current account deficits in recent quarters (Chart 3 and 4),
and those deficits would only widen if international oil prices continue
to rise. In these circumstances, even if the protests of exporters are
dismissed, a process that renders exports more expensive in dollar terms
and imports cheaper in rupee terms cannot be ignored. That is ''success''
on the capital account of the balance of payments cannot beyond a point
be at the expense of a weakening of the current account and the domestic
economy.
Further, rising inflation is forcing the Reserve Bank of India to turn
its attention to what has always been its primary brief: using the monetary
level to moderate price increases. One way in which it is expected to
do this is by raising interest rates and reducing offtake of credit
to cool an overheating system. But raising domestic interest rates would
only encourage further those investors exploiting international interest
rate differentials and engaging in the carry trade. Being relevant on
the price management front may make the central bank an even greater
failure with regard to exchange rate management.
The real option is, therefore, one of dealing with the source of the
problem and using measures to control the inflow of financial capital,
especially speculative capital. There are many policy options at hand
to achieve this end. What is required is that a government that had
perceived the surge in capital inflows and the accumulation of reserves
as being indicators of economic success admits that even in its own
framework this is proving to be too much of a good thing.