It
is often said that "India lives in its states". This is obviously
true, but it is also increasingly becoming a means of passing on governmental
responsibility from central to state levels. Under the Constitution, State
governments have always had very significant responsibilities (for law
and order, infrastructure development, health, education, agriculture
– to name just a few). However, at the same time they have not had commensurate
powers either to raise resources or to influence broader trends that create
the context or enabling conditions for fulfilling these responsibilities.
The assigning of responsibility to states particularly for economic outcomes
is now becoming even more pronounced in the central government. Thus,
in the past week Ministers in the Central Government Cabinet have argued
that the recent rise in the rate of inflation is the problem of state
governments and must be dealt with by them. Yet inflation is so clearly
a macroeconomic process that it is obviously determined by aggregate national
forces and policies. These include not only fiscal and monetary policies,
which are the sole preserve of the central government, but also trade
policies and other features that state governments cannot determine but
must only respond to.
A wide range of other actions – for example, enactment and enforcement
of a Right to Education Bill for the entire country – are being held up
or undermined on spurious concerns about federalism. At the same time,
it is now common to hear central government spokesmen argue that "the
states are now flush with funds" because of the increase in sales
taxes and therefore do not require further transfer of financial resources
from the Centre. The basic difference between Centre and States – that
state governments necessarily face a hard budget constraint unlike the
central government – is forgotten in this context. Also, since the state
governments cannot impose service taxes, and therefore must exclude the
fastest growing segment of the economy from their resource raising efforts,
means that they are at a significant disadvantage compared to the central
government in this regard.
The basic means of financial transfer is through the successive Finance
Commissions, which are supposed to ensure a fair and equitable devolution
of fiscal resources from the Centre to States. However, the terms of reference
of recent Finance Commissions have gone beyond the simple allocation of
tax revenues between Centre and different States according to a given
formula, to allowing and even proposing conditional transfers, even if
this goes against the basic principle of federal devolution. Thus, the
Eleventh Finance Commission proposed a system of debt relief to states
which required them to first pass fiscal responsibility legislation according
to parameters laid down by the Centre.
For all the talk of decentralisation, this actually amounts to a greater
centralisation of government finances. Direct central allocations to states
are increasingly covered by conditionalities, even if they are egregious
or unsuitable to the state in question. A case in point is the transfer
of funds under the Jawaharlal Nehru National Urban Renewal Mission (JNNURM),
which requires problematic measures such as the elimination of stamp duty
by recipient state governments. Or they are so rigid as to make it difficult
to adjust the funding to local requirements, as in the case of the Sarva
Shiksha Abhiyan (SSA) where exactly the same norms for expenditure are
laid down for all states regardless of differing contexts.
Another attempt to undermine federalism and the authority of elected state
governments comes in the arguments for fiscal provisions by the Centre
directly to panchayats at district level. With norms for expenditure determined
by the Centre, as well as "capacity building" of panchayat members
by the Centre, this amounts to an extremely centralised notion of decentralisation,
where the real decisions are made at the very top of national government
rather than being delegated to states and then to panchayats.
In this context, what is the current situation with respect to the fiscal
health of states and financial devolution? Chart 1 describes the pattern
of deficit among all state governments taken together. It is evident that
the severe fiscal crisis of the states that was so marked in the early
years of this decade is no longer as pervasive. Since 2004 all the major
deficit indicators have been declining, and the revenue and primary deficits
are now close to zero for the states as a whole. Even the fiscal deficit
total is under 3 per cent of GDP.
It
is generally supposed that this improved fiscal health is the reuslt
of the Eleventh Finance Commisison’s award, which is perceived ot have
substantially increased grants to states and also allowed some debt
write-off to those states that agreed to pass the controversial fiscal
responsbility legislation. However, Chart 2 indicates that such a conclusion
is not justified. In fact, the significant increase has been in tax
receipts of the state governments themselves, which in 2006-07 accounted
for more than 55 per cent of their total fiscal resources.
The
share in central taxes has remained small and shown hardly any increase
as a proportion of total receipts. Even all non-tax receipts (which
include grants from the Centre as the biggest chunk) have not increased
veyr much and remain at less than a quarter of total receipts. It is
worth noting that the share of capital receipts has declined very sharply
in recent years.
The
relatively low and even declining share of central taxes is confimred
by the evidence on the states’ share of central taxes as a proportion
of the totla central tax collection. Chart 3 shows that this has been
declining since the most recent peak of 2001-02, and that the average
of the last three years (2004-05 to 2006-07) is well below the average
of the three-year period of a decade earlier. All the state government
taken together currently receive just around one quarter of central
tax revenues, even though they are directly responsible for most of
the public service delivery that directly affects the lives of people.
What
of the total financial devolution, that is including grants and
all other mechanisms? In current nominal terms that has certainly
been rising, as indicated by Chart 4 which show the nominal rate
of growth on the right hand scale. However, as share of GDP of states
they have been mostly stganant in the recent period, and indicate
some evidence of medium-term decline compared to the early 1990s.
It was noted earlier that capital receipts had been declining as
a percentage of total state governments’ receipts, and stood at
only 21 per cent in 2006-07. Within this, however, the share of
market borrowings increased, as evident from Chart 5 which exmaines
the nature of financing the fiscal deficit for all states. In the
last three years described here there has also been a sharp increase
in use of small svaings (the NSSF or Natioanl Small Savings Fund)
which reflects the shift in personal savings away from bank deposits
to small savings because of interest rate differentials. This of
course means that state governments have had to pay relatively higher
rates of interest on borrowing even in the period of lower interest
rates on average, but at least they automatically receive most of
these funds. Evidence from 2007-08 suggests that this was not forthcoming
last year. Meanwhile, loans from the central government have declined
to the point of irrelevance.
It is sometimes believed that grant funds, which
are non-interest bearing and supposedly untied, allow a greater degree
of comfort and flexibility to states, and indeed the Eleventh Finance
Commission put more emphasis on grants for thosereaosns, as well as
because of the perceived decline in aggregate tax-GDP ratios. However,
a substantial proportion of the grants provided to the States come
in the form of Central Schemes and Centrally Sponsored Schemes.
Chart 6 shows that not only are these significant, but they have also
been increasing as a proportion of total grants in the recent period.
Strictly speaking, transfers for Central Schemes should not be included
in such grants at all or counted as part of devolved resources, since
they reflect central government expenditure that is simply administered
by states. Centrally Sponsored Scehemes are also problematic since
they typically require matching expenditure by states (of varying
proportions acording to Scheme) and are in any case completely determined
by the Centre, in terms of content, structure, format and process.
So they cannot really be described as devolved funds at all. This
is especially the case given the significant increase in different
forms of conditionality that now accompany most if not all Centrally
Sponsored Schemes. However, it is apparent from Chart 6 that more
than one-fourth of all grants to States come in these centralised
forms.
All this suggests that fiscal federalism still remains somewhat of
an empty promise in India, despite all the protestations to the contrary.
If this is indeed the case, and the central government continues to
control the bulk of public finances in India, then surely it should
also take more responsibility for the eocnomic and social outcomes
that are determined by poublic spending.
|