Print this page
Themes > Features
10.04.2003

Forms of Dualism: An Analysis of the Structure of India's Unregistered Manufacturing Sector Based on the
56th Round Results

Despite more than five decades of state-led industrial development, 'dualism' even 'multi-structuralism', has been an abiding characteristic of India's industrial sector. Early analyses of the structure of industry at independence had pointed to the domination of 'lower forms of production', or production characterized by the use of non-power-driven techniques, and the absence of hired labour in predominantly rural and semi-urban areas. Thus, according to the national income data relating to 1948–49, 'factory establishments' accounted for just 6.34 per cent of national income, while 37 per cent was generated in the mining and manufacturing sectors1. Further, going by the 1951 Census, factory establishments accounted for just 26 per cent of the employment in mining and manufacturing, which in turn amounted to only 9.3 per cent of total employment2.

Although organized sector units, or those that correspond to the registration criteria set by sections 2m(i) and 2m(ii) of the Factories Act of 1948, are not always units that reflect the attributes of modern industrial establishments, this is the closest one can get to making a division between the unorganized and organized, or informal and formal, a classification that must necessarily be arbitrary. However, since by law these units have to meet the requirements of labour legislation in the country, this is at least one sense in which they may be termed formal or organized.

Conventional wisdom based on the experience of developed countries would have it that industrialization is process in which an economy witnesses the gradual demise of excessively small units and units based on primitive techniques and primitive forms of organization, which give way to large or larger units working with hired labour and more advanced techniques and increasingly adopting the impersonal joint-stock company form of organization. It hardly bears stating that state intervention to ensure minimum wage payments, a 'normal' working day and reasonable conditions of work, by encouraging productivity-enhancing technical change, contributes to the above-described transition.

This would imply, as a corollary, that the implicit 'exemption' from regulation of units that do not meet the criteria set by sections 2m(i) and 2m(ii) would itself slow the pace of 'modernization' and contribute to some degree of persistence of dualism. This is a factor that favours the use of the Factories Act definition to draw the dividing line between the organized and unorganized sectors. In addition, since historically the statistical system has sought to cover registered units through the Annual Survey of Industries (ASI), and unregistered units through the Economic Censuses and the follow-up surveys undertaken by the National Sample Survey Organization (NSSO), a body of statistical evidence exists to assess the structure and evolution of the unregistered sector.

Needless to say, dualism is not just a function of the implementation of the Factories Act, allowing for wage differentials between the 'organized' and 'unorganized' sectors. Rather, as analysts have often pointed out, a number of other factors on the demand side, such as the persistence of 'traditional tastes' that can be catered to only by more primitive techniques, and the existence of poverty and inadequate market integration, which generate a different kind of 'niche' market for cheap but primitive products, have also encouraged dualism. Further, inasmuch as poverty-inducing factors like unemployment and underemployment result in a constant search by the poor for supplementary work, and since barriers to entry into many areas of unorganized production are limited, the supply of commodities from these unorganized sector units tends to be elastic, with production occurring at extremely low wages and prices that reflect small or negligible 'margins', as when the above-mentioned demands manifest themselves. In the event, the unregistered manufacturing sector would be characterized by three kinds of 'instability'-that stemming from the fact that some of its activities are seasonal; that resulting from the high rate of mortality of unregistered units, given low wages, small margins and extreme competition, and that resulting from the precariousness of the demands it caters to.

Besides all these, backward techniques and backward forms of organization survive also because of the subordination of these activities by merchant or trading capital, which is able to earn for itself a suitable margin even while remaining competitive with production based on modern techniques because of its ability to exploit the benefits of the low wages associated with production in the unorganized or unregistered sector. This is particularly true of primitive production units that cater to national markets, like handloom, beedi and match production units. In fact, the irrational concentration of match production in a few contiguous districts of Tamil Nadu, accounting for an overwhelming share of the matches produced in the country and catering to markets nationwide, can only be explained by a trading chain dominated by merchant capital that controls a complex, historically evolved production system involving home- and unit-based female and child labour and extremely low costs of production.

Thus 'dualism' or 'multi-structuralism' is not determined primarily by the existence or otherwise of factory legislation, but is a consequence of the larger socio-economic context and its evolution. The Factories Act merely provides an arbitrary dividing line to be drawn between the organized and unorganized sectors, and an ambiguous contribution to the differences between the two sectors. 'Ambiguous' because, evidence regarding the enforcement of the Factories Act does not inspire confidence in the ability of the implementing mechanism to ensure minimum wages and reasonable conditions of work in the factories that are formally registered with the Chief Inspector of Factories.

This note has a limited objective: to delineate the structure of the unregistered manufacturing sector on the basis of data yielded by the 56th Round of the NSS, conducted during July 2000 and July 2001. The 56th Round covered all unorganized manufacturing enterprises (UMEs) under the two digit codes 15 to 37 and enterprises under cotton-ginning, cleaning and baling3. Out of these 5,586 rural and 8,942 urban units were finally surveyed. The survey covered manufacturing enterprises (MEs) not covered in the
(ASI)4 (i.e. those not registered under Section 2m(i) and 2m(ii) of the Factories Act 1948), manufacturing enterprises registered under Section 85 of the Factories Act, 1948, and enterprises manufacturing beedis and cigars that are not covered under the ASI.

The NSS estimates the total number of workers employed in the unregistered manufacturing sector in 2000–01 at 3.71 crore. If we exclude industries with NIC codes 01405 and 37, and compare the remaining industries with the same set of 22 two-digit industries in the ASI, we find that the 3.71 crore workers in the unregistered sector in 2000–01 compare with 79 lakh workers in the registered factory sector in 1999–2000. Assuming no change in the number of workers between 1999–2000 and 2000–01 in ASI factories5, the share of the unregistered sector in total manufacturing employment thus works out to 82 per cent. Similarly, gross value added in the unregistered sector of the 22 two-digit industries mentioned above in 2000–01 by the product approach works out to 24.3 per cent of the combined gross value added in registered manufacturing in 1999–2000 and unregistered manufacturing in 2000–016.(Interestingly, this is substantially different from the contribution of the unregistered sector to manufacturing GDP, which is placed by National Accounts Statistics at 35 per cent in 2000–01.) Clearly, therefore, if the figures relating to the immediate post-independence years are reliable, the importance of the unregistered manufacturing sector has increased significantly in employment terms, even if its contribution has fallen in terms of value added shares.

While the unregistered sector accounts for a significant share of manufacturing employment and production, the structure of the sector remains heavily biased in favour of small and organizationally 'primitive' units. Across rural and urban areas, own account manufacturing enterprises (OAMEs), or those that employ no hired labour on a 'regular basis', account for an overwhelming 86 per cent of all enterprises. Though the presence of OAMEs is greater in rural areas, their share in total enterprises in urban areas too amounts to a remarkable 71 per cent. Further, both in rural and urban areas, more than 70 per cent of the units employing hired workers are non-directory manufacturing establishments, or those employing less than six workers.

                             

Table 2 provides a picture of the two-digit industrial categories in which OAMEs account for less than 80 per cent of all enterprises in rural areas, and 66 per cent of all enterprises in urban areas. While in the rural areas there are just 7 of the 24 industries covered by the 56th Round that meet these stringent criteria, there are 14 out of 24 in the urban areas in which less than two-thirds of the units are OAMEs. Further, these sectors account for less than 1 and 15 per cent, respectively, of all enterprises in rural and urban areas. Clearly, the spread of production based on use of hired labour on a fairly regular basis is limited within the unregistered sector in both rural and urban areas.
 
    

In addition to the persistence of small-sized units and non-hired labour-based forms of organization, the structure of the unregistered sector points to a relatively high degree of specialization of activity when analysed in terms of two-digit categories. Thus as far as OAMEs are concerned as many as 60 per cent of the total are food, tobacco, textile and garment units, in both rural and urban areas. In the rural areas, if we add wood and wood product units, the cumulative share rises to as much as 83 per cent. Thus, small OAMEs are concentrated in traditional areas such as food products, textiles and wood products, all of which are agro-based rather than chemical or metal-based. Even NDMEs and DMEs, account for 60 to 75 per cent of the total in rural areas and around 45 per cent in urban areas. The other two areas with a significant number of enterprises are non-metallic mineral products, especially in the DME category in rural areas, and fabricated metal products, excluding machinery and equipment. The former, we must recall, includes activities such as manufacture of glass and glass products (including glass bangles), ceramic ware, bricks, roofing tiles and lime and plaster, all activities that fall within the broad definition of 'traditional' and can be seen as predominantly catering to local markets.

    

The concentration of activity in these areas is visible even when assessed in terms of the share of employment in unregistered units in different two-digit industrial categories. Food, tobacco, textile and wood products account for between 50 and 82 per cent of employment in OAMEs and NDMEs, and if we include non-metallic mineral products and fabricated metal products, the ratio rises to 85 to 90 per cent for all kinds of units.

      

The primitive nature of a substantial segment of the unregistered manufacturing sector is also reflected in the fact that 70 per cent of all units are typically 'household units', in the sense that they are located in household premises. This high proportion is of course explained primarily by OAMEs dominating the sector in terms of number of enterprises and as many as 80 per cent of OAMEs in rural areas and 70 per cent in urban areas being located in household premises. But what is noteworthy is the fact that 35 and 22 per cent of NDMEs in rural and urban areas respectively, and 26 and 20 per cent of DMEs, are household units. If operating out of permanent, non-household premises is taken as a minimal prerequisite for a unit being a 'modern' small unit in the unregistered sector, then, only a little more than a half of the small population of NDMEs and DMEs in rural areas and about three-quarters of NDMEs and DMEs in the urban areas would qualify as modern small units or their precursors.
 
 

Another way to situate and assess the character of the unregistered manufacturing sector is to examine the degree and nature of its integration with the formal economy. This integration can occur either through financial, input–output or marketing linkages. These linkages may in fact complement each other, with financially-dependent small unregistered units obtaining inputs from and supplying their outputs to large players who provide financial assistance. With nearly 50 per cent of the units surveyed in the 56th round reporting 'shortage of capital' as the problem confronting them, these kinds of inter-linkages across finance, input and product markets is a real possibility.

It needs to be made clear, however, that none of these needs to be always positive from the point of view of units in the unregistered sector. As mentioned earlier, financial dependence could subordination to medium or large finance capital, especially in industries catering to large, state or national markets, which could have as a corollary relatively small margins, as is known to be true in the production of matches, beedis and handloom textiles. Input dependence on large oligopolistic suppliers could also imply high input prices that squeeze the margins in a sector where demand growth may be sluggish and the competition intense. And dependence on the supply of outputs as inputs and products for marketing by large units can make the small units bear the brunt of any downturn (through delayed payments, for example) or hard bargaining by oligopsonistic buyers who can squeeze margins substantially.


    

As Table 6 indicates, evidence yielded by the 56th Round suggests that an inter-linkage between the formal and informal sectors is indeed present, even if not overwhelming. Thus, 28 per cent of units in rural areas and 38 per cent of units in urban areas work on contracts, which are likely to be with units or capital from the formal sector. What is noteworthy is that in the rural areas and, to a smaller extent, in the urban areas, the contract system is more prevalent among OAMEs than establishments, pointing to the possibility of penetration by merchant capital in search of cheap home-based production sources that ensure the required returns. This presumption is supported by the evidence that, on average, 80 per cent of the enterprises working under the contract system enter into contracts solely with a master contractor/enterprise.

 

Contractual links notwithstanding, it does not appear from the evidence that these have dominated the choice of product markets for unregistered units: 65 per cent of rural units and 57 per cent of urban units reported that they sold some of their final output to private individuals or households. However, in the case of NDMEs and DMEs, sale of final output to private enterprises or contractors/middlemen was reported. About 37 and 55 per cent of NDMEs and DMEs respectively in rural areas, and 45 and 71 per cent respectively in urban areas reported such sales. Therefore, some kind of input–output linkage and ancillarization do seem to be widely prevalent.

 

In sum, we can think of two kinds of 'dualism' in the unregistered sector. First, dualism with respect to the formal sector, as reflected in the persistence of household units with primitive techniques even while modern industry progresses, even if not in terms of employment generated. This kind of dualism need not, however, imply the lack of any linkages with the formal sector. Rather, financial, input–output and marketing linkages can exist. The persistence of backwardness may not reflect just the existence of the peculiar niche markets that low per capita incomes and poverty create but also the subordination of backward forms by capital from the formal sector, which treats a segment of the unregistered sector as a source of surplus even if that is at the expense of extremely low wages. Second, dualism reflected by the signs of coexistence of backward units with other units, especially among the NDMEs and DMEs, which are taking on characteristics of ancillaries that are typical of any modern industrial environment. Analysts argue that the growth of these kinds of small units and their integration with the large-scale sector through a process of 'ancillarization' is positive from the point of view of generating a modern, well-managed small industrial sector.

The point to note is that while there is a strong positive relationship between the rank of a two-digit industrial sector in terms of estimated number of enterprises and estimated number of workers (with the rank correlation coefficient exceeding 0.9 in categories of units excepting NDMEs and DMEs in rural areas), there is virtually no relationship or at best an extremely weak relationship between the rank of an industry in terms of estimated number of workers and in terms of value added per worker. While it could be argued that this should be 'expected', what it does suggest is that in terms of the number of enterprises and estimated workers, it is not the more productive units that predominate. Features of this kind that emerge from this preliminary analysis of the 56th Round results suggest that the Indian context is surprising inasmuch as the long experience with industrialization has not undermined the former type of units, which in fact not only persist but even appear to dominate the landscape of the world of unregistered units.


[1] Computed from CSO figures quoted in Reserve Bank of India (1956), Report on Currency and Finance, RBI: Bombay, p. 127.
[2] Ref. Shirokov, G.K. (1973), Industrialization of India, Moscow: Progress Publishers.
[3] The Survey covered almost the entire country except Leh and Kargil districts in Jammu and Kashmir, villages beyond five kilometers of bus routes in Nagaland, inaccessible villages in Andaman & Nicobar Islands, and some first stage units where EC 1998 couldn't be undertaken. A total of 14788 first stage units (5696 villages and 9092 urban blocks) were selected for the survey.
[4] Enterprises with power with ten people or less, or those without power with 20 people or less are left out of the purview of the Factories Act 1948. 
[5] We must recall that the total number of workers in ASI factories fell from 85.5 lakh to 81.7 lakh between 1998-99 and 1999-2000.
[6] Inflating the 1999-2000 ASI GVA figure using the rate of growth of that magnitude between 1998-99 and 1999-2000 to arrive at an estimate for 2000-01 and using that figure changes the ratio to 22.9 per cent as opposed to 23.4 per cent.

 

© MACROSCAN 2003