It is rare for the
Reserve Bank of India to make very definitive and even partisan
statements about the broad contours of economic strategy. Central bank
reports are normally fairly staid documents, attempting to present
balanced if boring analyses of economic trends and policies. Over the
past decade, as the other official economic publications have tended to
be like publicity hand-outs for the government rather than objective
assessments of the state of the economy, the RBI's publications have
been more circumspect.
All that seems to be changing, along with so much else in economic
institutions in India. The latest Currency and Finance Report of
the RBI (officially referring to 2001–02 but published in April 2003) is
for the first time organized around a theme: no less than an assessment
of the economic reforms programme of the Government of India since 1991.
It is a bold attempt, and certainly valuable, given that it comes from
this particular official quarter. The foreword (by RBI Deputy Governor
Rakesh Mohan) and the opening chapter (on the theme of the report) give
some indication of the underlying bias: 'The country has gained
significantly from policy reforms in the 1990s. Further gains are there
for the taking.' (pages I–3)
While it may be unusual for an official document to so openly wear its
heart on its sleeve, it must be said that the subsequent chapters are
much more carefully worked and worded. The various chapters present
surveys of the literature and assessment of the team of writers, as well
as a set of data pertaining to trends in the real economy, fiscal and
monetary policy, the financial sector and the external sector.
Of course, there are major gaps and limitations even in the presentation
of the broad trends. Thus, the entire report contains no mention of
employment trends, as if employment is not and need not be a central
concern of macroeconomic policy. Similarly, the report tends to
uncritically accept the disputed argument that there has been a dramatic
decline in the incidence of poverty, which is based on non-comparable
consumption surveys conducted by the NSSO. Nevertheless, there is much
in the report that provides an interesting and useful account of the
economy under neo-liberal reforms.
Much of the trend analysis is conducted by comparing the pre-reform
decade (here defined as 1982–82 to 1990–91) and the post-reform period
(1992–93 to 2002–03), thereby excluding the 'crisis year' 1991–92 from
the calculations. These data themselves tend to give the lie to the more
optimistic assessment of the reforms that is presented in the overview
chapter of the report, since they reveal a number of weaknesses even in
the aggregate growth patterns.
In this edition of Macroscan, we focus on the evidence presented in the
report on real economic growth, and consider the experience thus far
with sectoral growth performance, as well as the underlying reasons for
such performance.
To begin
with, very recent trends in the economy suggest that economic activity
has not only decelerated but is far below potential. Chart 1 shows that
there is clear indication of deceleration in aggregate growth of GDP,
despite fluctuations, in the last three years. This has been led by the
poor performance of agriculture and allied sectors, but industrial
growth also appears to be low over the recent period. Indeed, only the
services sector shows relatively high growth rates, and even those have
decelerated over the last three years.
This is
related to the deceleration in investment ratios, evident from Chart 2.
There has been a long-run tendency for savings and investment rates (as
shares of GDP) to increase, reflecting the usual pattern in
industrializing economies. However, this tendency appears to have come
to a halt by the mid-1990s, and, by the early years of the current
decade, the investment ratio had settled at between 23 and 24 per cent.
More disturbing, the savings rate actually exceeded the investment rate
in 2001–02 (and most probably also in 2002–03, for which the NAS data
are not yet available).
This is an indication of the extent of slack in
the economy, the aggregate unemployment and under-utilization of
capacity. There is no question that the economy is operating well below
potential, and the RBI also accepts this diagnosis. However, the RBI's
own estimates of the potential income and the output gap are not based
on the full deployment of existing resources. Rather, potential output
is defined by some notion of 'structural factors' such as 'the lack of
appropriate (undefined) reforms in the agricultural sector,
infrastructure rigidities, labour market rigidities, weak bankruptcy and
exit procedures’, which suggests that it is also operating within the
narrow conceptual confines of the liberalizers.
The trend analysis of GDP confirms the picture of deceleration,
especially over the most recent period. The RBI has calculated
semi-logarithmic trend rates of growth for the relevant periods. While
the trend growth rate of aggregate GDP is estimated to have increased
from 5.6 per cent over 1981–82 to 1990–91, to 6.1 per cent in the period
1992–93 to 2002–03, this masks very differential performance across
sectors. In fact, as Charts 3 to 10 show, both the primary and secondary
sectors, as well as some important tertiary sectors have experienced
deceleration of growth along with much greater volatility of growth as
expressed in the coefficient of variation.
The sharpest
deceleration is observed in agriculture, as apparent from Chart 3. It is
worth remembering that the primary sector's long-run trend rate of
growth since independence has been 3 per cent, and the post-reform
period marks the first phase when it has actually fallen well below
that. Indeed, this low rate of growth reflects the stagnation or even
decline of agriculture in the more recent period, as we will discuss
below.
It is true
that this lower growth of agricultural GDP has been associated with
lower volatility as well, but that reflects the tendency to stagnation
especially in the latter part of the period. The report provides
insufficient attention to the causes of this, and tends to underplay one
of the more important aspects that has affected value added in
agriculture (as opposed to gross production)-the impact of trade
liberalization in keeping down many crop prices even when domestic
output falls.
Mining and quarrying is clearly one of the sectors that has been
adversely affected in the last decade. Chart 4 shows that GDP growth in
this sector has decelerated; meanwhile, there is also much greater
volatility of such growth. The coefficient of variation of GDP in this
sub-sector was as high as 85 per cent in the latter period.
Manufacturing is more crucial to the Indian economy, and therefore it is
disturbing to see from Chart 5 that the same tendencies are operative
for this sub-sector as well. Deceleration of output growth has been
accompanied by increased fluctuations, and it will become apparent that
this is related to the even sharper slowdown in manufacturing in the
latter part of the period.
This was accompanied by substantial slowdown and
similar increase in volatility of the infrastructure and utility
sectors, that are so important for manufacturing growth as
well-electricity, gas and water supply (Chart 6).
It is only
the services sub-sectors, described in Charts 7 to 10, that suggested
any increase in rates of growth, and that is primarily why GDP growth in
the aggregate has remained respectable. Even here, however, financing,
insurance, real estate and business services registered a significant
slowdown. Also, the acceleration in output growth of community, social
and personal services may not reflect a real increase so much as the
increase in public sector wages that occurred over this period because
of the Pay Commission awards.
What explains
this general deceleration in output growth in most sectors? The RBI
report suggests that this reflects the more significant slowdown that
has occurred after 1996, and therefore breaks down the post-reform
period into three sub-periods for more detailed consideration.
Chart 11
gives some idea of this. It is clear that agricultural deceleration was
the most advanced, with GDP growth in agriculture in the final five-year
period averaging only 1 per cent per annum. But even manufacturing shows
a sharp slowdown, falling in the last five years to only 4.2 per cent
per annum-one of the lowest trend rates of growth experienced for Indian
manufacturing in any period since the 1950s.
The stability of
services growth over this period was clearly inadequate to counter these
recessionary trends, which is why the period 1997–98 to 2002–03 also
shows aggregate GDP growth at a lower rate of 5.3 per cent.
Over this later period, savings rates also declined on average. Chart 12
indicates that this was primarily due to the collapse of public sector
savings, as the public sector became a net dissaver. Indeed, savings was
kept afloat essentially by the household sector, since private corporate
savings also declined as a share of GDP over this period.
Chart 13
takes a closer look at the distribution of household financial savings
over the various five-year periods since the early 1980s. A number of
features emerge from this chart. Currency has been declining as a share
of total household financial savings, while more secure financial
instruments have been gradually increasing. These include life insurance
funds and net claims to the government (the so-called 'small savings').
Significantly, bank deposits have been growing in proportion throughout
this period. Stockmarket instruments-shares and debentures-increased in
the early 1990s, but after the stockmarket scam, households clearly
decided to stick to less risky forms of saving. By the last sub-period
they accounted for only 5 per cent of household financial instruments.
The swing away from such stockmarket instruments clearly seems to have
benefited small savings in the last period.
Investment rates also declined on average in the last sub-period, as
illustrated by Chart 14. Interestingly, the decline in investment showed
both public and private sector investment deceleration, while the
household sector actually increased its investment (which is the same as
its physical savings). This is but another reflection of the increasing
slack, or unemployment and underutilization of resources, in the
macroeconomy, that has already been mentioned.
Public
sector investment was constrained by the falling tax–GDP ratios and the
official perception that fiscal deficits needed to be contained, which
meant cutbacks on public capital expenditure. There is no surprise in
the associated decline in private corporate investment rates-the strong
positive link between public and private investment in India (and indeed
in most developing countries) is by now well-established, and the fact
of recessionary tendencies in the economy during this period is also
widely accepted.
The slowdown in manufacturing deserves closer attention. As Chart 15
shows, such deceleration was spread across a very wide range of
manufacturing sub-sectors. So much so that only five sub-sectors appear
to have bucked the adverse trend: beverages and tobacco, textile
products, leather, chemicals and rubber, plastics petroleum and coal.
For most of traditional manufacturing, as well as for the range of
capital goods industries, the falls in growth rate were actually quite
steep.
The RBI
report considers at some length the various hypotheses advanced to
explain the deceleration. It mentions the argument that has been
advanced by Macroscan earlier, that the slowdown reflected the satiation
of pent-up demand once the initial spurt of import-intensive production
had dealt with post-liberalization consumer demand. Once that
once-for-all increase had been catered to, manufacturing faced a
recession in the absence of any further demand impetus, either from the
domestic economy or through exports. This was aided by the fact that the
initial early 1990s' expansion had not greatly increase employment, and
so had limited linkage and multiplier effects.
The RBI appears to reject this argument, on the grounds that 'the huge
capacity build up noticed in the first phase of reform runs counter to
the monetary surge in demand that was not likely to be sustained in the
long run' (pages III–30). However, this counter-argument is weak at
best, and is actually contradicted by the data provided in the very same
report, on capital goods production and import. It will be seen from
Chart 16, that both domestic production and imports of capital goods
really increased in the middle of the 1990s, and peaked by 1997–98, when
the onset of domestic recession from 1996 finally dampened investor
expectations. Since then, both production and imports of capital goods
have been relatively depressed, indicating that investor expectations
have yet to recover in the absence of any stimulus either from the
government or from the external sector.
In addition, the report argues that the fall in
government investment does not per se provide a satisfactory
explanation of the slowdown, since government productive expenditure
also declined during the short-lived boom. But that is precisely the
point: that after that initial import-led consumption boom was over, the
slowdown in government investment made things worse because there was no
additional stimulus to private investment.
In contrast, the other explanations that have been offered for the
manufacturing slowdown, which are apparently taken more seriously by the
report, are almost laughable. The first relates to the 'credit crunch'
faced by the corporate sector during 1995–96, when the RBI made large
dollar sales to contain foreign currency market volatility. This could
hardly explain the continued depression in investment until 2002–03. The
important point about the credit market, which is not made in the
report, is that the reduced access of small-scale industry to formal
credit after financial deregulation has dramatically weakened its
position and contributed substantially to the slowdown.
Similarly, the report argues that 'the proportion of corporate funds
locked up in inventories and receivables went up steadily, leading to a
scarcity of working capital' (pages III–30). This argument surely
mistakes cause for effect-the increase in inventories is typically a
sign of recession, not a factor determining it.
The report also mentions the role of cyclical factors, such as the
lagged effect of low agricultural growth and the depressed international
economic context. What it fails to mention is that it is precisely in
such circumstances that expansion must come from government expenditure.
This reflects the basic constraint within which the report has been
written, that it is operating very much within the paradigm of the
marketist neo-liberal reform that the policy-makers in the Finance and
other ministries have adopted. In the circumstances, it is hardly
surprising that the Report is unable, despite its apparent intentions,
actually to offer an objective assessment of the Indian reform
experience.