Primary commodity prices
are well known to be highly volatile. Indeed, they are not just subject
to short boom and bust cycles driven by demand and supply shocks, but
also longer term cycles and secular trends driven by more structural
and evolutionary forces.
There are many reasons for such volatility. First there is the strong
relationship between climatic change and weather conditions. What is
often less noted is the fact that even demand conditions are affected
by weather, such as the demand for oil. Since the demand for most primary
commodities is anyway less price-elastic than for manufactures, this
means that any variability in supply gets associated with far greater
price variability than in the case of manufactured goods.
In the case of perishable commodities, supply is inevitably very inelastic
in the short term. For certain other primary commodities such as tree
crops, the complete production process takes considerable time so that
shifts in demand have a large impact on price in the intervening period.
For perishable primary commodities in particular, the costs of holding
inventories tend to be high, which further affects price response. Since
holding inventories of virtually all primary commodities, even the non-perishable
ones, tends to involve significant costs, they are in turn significantly
affected by the prevailing rate of interest. Thus movements in the rate
of interest, which change the costs of holding these inventories, can
be associated with changes in product price as such stocks are released
to or withdrawn from the market by private traders. This tendency, which
was noticed a century ago, is still an important element in the various
forces making for commodity price volatility.
Indeed, even producers' organisations which are often intended to stabilise
world market prices in particular commodities can have the opposite
effect if they contribute to volatility through large shifts in supply.
One example of this is OPEC, which has certainly affected international
oil prices through its changing decisions on production and supply.
However, even by the standards of the past, the volatility of primary
commodity prices appears to have increased quite dramatically in the
past two decades. As Chart 1 indicates, primary commodity prices have
been more volatile than the prices of manufactures in the last two decades,
and both oil prices and non-oil commodity prices have fallen relative
to the prices of manufactures. The chart provides data from the World
Bank for the period from 1984 to late 1999. The unit value index of
manufactures in this chart relates to the manufactures exported from
the G5 countries (France, Germany, Japan, United Kingdom, and
United States) weighted by the country's exports to developing countries.
This evidence of higher
volatility is confirmed by other studies, all of which suggest that
the volatility of primary commodity prices increased sharply following
the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in the early 1970s and has
remained high thereafter, going up further in the 1990s. According to
the World Bank publication Global Economic Prospects for Developing
Countries 2000, the standard deviation of the absolute value of
the year-on-year changes in the non-energy commodity price index during
197098 was 11.5, compared with 5.7 for the manufactures unit value
index during the same period.
Within this general category, it is clear that energy prices have been
particularly volatile. According to the same source, measured in US
dollars, the coefficient of variation of energy prices was at least
twice that of manufactures in each decade. The world oil market has
been especially unstable over the 1990s. Peak prices during the Gulf
War, price declines related to restructuring and non-OPEC supply subsequently,
revival in the mid-1990s, falling prices and stock build-up combining
with relatively warmer weather to produce a complete collapse. in 1998.
By late 1998, many observers were predicting that energy prices would
stay low for the coming decade, and within months this prediction was
confounded by the Pheonix-like emergence of oil prices in 1999 to almost
regain the level of the pre-collapse period.
Of course, oil prices are a special case because of the very different
circumstances of global trade in energy, which have once again underlined
the crucial role played by OPEC decisions in setting international prices
in this sector. But it is worth noting that in general non-oil prices
have certainly followed similar long-terms trends, and are now displaying
similar (if less marked) volatility.
Not only has price volatility been a problem, but commodity prices have
also declined relative to manufactures' prices during the past two decades.
According to the World Bank, the real price indexes (nominal price indexes
divided by the manufactures unit value index) of both agriculture and
metals and minerals fell by about 45 percent during 1980- 98. It is
now widely accepted that the decline in the ratio of the price of primary
products to manufactures is statistically significant.
Energy prices have fallen by 76 percent in real terms since 1980 and
in 1998 were less than half the level reached after the first oil price
rise in 197374. Even with the recovery in 1999, the real energy
price index likely will remain at only 55 percent of the 1974 level.
As is evident from Chart 2 and 3, the past two years have been especially
bad for absolute levels of prices as well. After the mini-boom of 1994-96,
there has been a fall in all the major commodity groups, which has been
substantially related to both supply behaviour and demand changes, led
for example by the east Asian crisis from mid-1997.
It is clear that supply
conditions have played a role in depressing commodity prices, especially
for agricultural and mineral goods. Thus, total world output of agricultural
goods increased by 1 per cent per annum in the period 1990-94. This
increased to 2.6 per annum over 1994-98. However, world consumption
of agricultural commodities is estimated to have grown at a much slower
rate.
The decline in primary commodity prices since 1997 was in part a response
to an unusually large increase in supply. The rate of growth of world
production of agricultural commodities rose from 1 percent per year
in 199094 to 2.6 percent in 199498, whereas world production
of metals and minerals was flat in 199094, but increased by 3.5
percent per year in 199498. 6 The acceleration of consumption
of primary commodities between the two periods was much less.
It could has been argued that increased production was in part a response
to the high prices that prevailed during the brief boom of 199395.
If that were the case, then the expectations of producers must have
been sorely disappointed, for agricultural commodities saw prices fall
by 4.5 per cent in 1996 then recover slightly in 1997 before dropping
by more than 16 per cent in 1998. The first ten months of 1999 saw such
prices continue to fall, by an average rate of 14 per cent. Declines
have been particularly pronounced for crops such as wheat, maize, coffee,
rubber and sugar, and in 1999 the depressive tendency also extended
to cocoa prices. However, as Chart 3 shows, the downturn has been fairly
general across broad categories of food, beverages and raw materials.
There is a parenthetical
point that deserves to be made here. These price movements have been
so sharp that they have in turn affected the domestic prices of such
commodities in countries where external trade has been increasingly
liberalised. This is a point often missed in India for example, where
discussion of the effects of trade liberalisation on Indian agriculture
are often still based on world prices that prevailed in 1996. Unlike
in that period, the current level of international prices of most agricultural
goods is such that they are well below Indian prices, and so expectations
of big increases in agricultural exports or resistance to import penetration
which remain based on the earlier prices are likely to be misplaced.
Meanwhile, minerals and metals products prices have been declining quite
sharply from 1995 onwards. As is clear from Chart 2, the cumulative
decline from then to 1999 amounts to nearly 25 per cent. Once again,
supply behaviour has played an important role : world production of
metals and minerals did not increase at all over 199094, but subsequently
increased by 3.5 percent per year in the period 199498.
The big falls in 1998 were of commodities that had already seen their
prices decline substantially in the previous years, such as aluminium,
copper, lead and zinc. The supply-demand imbalance is especially evident
in the case of these commodities. Aluminium production increased by
5 percent per year during 199597, while consumption grew by only
3 percent per year. Copper production grew by 6 percent from 1995 to
1997, while consumption grew by 4 percent. Nickel production increased
by more than 5 percent from 1995 to 1997, while consumption fell slightly.
The question, of course, is why there was such an increase in production.
The standard explanation has been in terms of lagged responses to the
relatively high prices of the mid-1990s. Another explanation has been
in terms of improved technology, in terms of innovations ranging from
improved seeds in agriculture to new solvent extraction techniques in
mining, and improvements in production processes like horizontal drilling
and increased computerisation.
These would certainly have played some role, but they are not likely
to provide a complete explanation. For one thing, the increase in production
of both minerals and metals as well as agricultural commodities in the
later period was much sharper for developing countries. The Food and
Agriculture Organisation's index of the volume of agricultural production
rose by 3.8 percent per year for all developing countries from 1990
to 1997. The global supplies of metals and minerals also increased rapidly,
more so for developing countries.
This difference is more likely to be related to other economic forces
than technology or a generalised prices response. In fact, many of the
largest increases in production came from countries whose economies
desperately had to generate foreign exchange to service external debt
and meet the bill for much-needed imports.
In other words, severe balance of payments pressures and structural
adjustment cum liberalisation strategies based on increased openness
had created a situation where many developing countries were increasingly
forced to rely on increasing volumes of traditional primary commodity
exports to generate foreign exchange for financial obligations as well
as to meet basic consumption, much of which had earlier been met by
domestic consumption. This pressure to generate higher export volumes
on the part of most of the developing country producers in turn had
a depressing effect on world prices.
Along with supply increases, demand conditions have also played a role
in the most recent cyclical decline of commodity prices. The proximate
cause that is always mentioned in this connection is the East Asian
crisis, which dramatically reduced import demand in the crisis countries
as well as created recessionary ripples which lowered consumption of
primary commodities in other countries as well. The is because the East
and Southeast Asian countries together with Japan account for very substantial
shares - between one-fourth and one-third - of world consumption of
most primary commodities.
This augurs ill for development prospects in these countries precisely
because of the two processes that have been highlighted so far in terms
of primary commodity prices : their volatility and their secular decline.
Given the high - and indeed, growing - degree of dependence of many
developing countries on primary commodity exports, the functioning of
these international markets has not been such as to give either a reasonable
possibility of sustained growth or freedom from the continuous need
to stabilise economies and smooth the savings and consumption patterns
over the relatively short and sharp price cycles.
These boom-and-bust cycles naturally impact on developing countries
as a group far more adversely than on industrial countries. After all,
primary commodities accounted for as much 42 per cent of all developing
countries' total merchandise exports in 1997, compared with only 19
per cent for the rich countries.
But still, even within developing countries, there are two groups that
have been the most affected by the most recent boom-bust cycle. The
first group consists of the major oil exporting countries, that is,
countries where oil accounts for more than 50 percent of merchandise
exports. The other group is that of the non-oil exporting countries
of Sub-Saharan Africa, where non-oil primary commodities, on average,
make up 80 percent of exports.
For some countries, especially the least developed countries of Sub-Saharan
Africa, primary commodities account for 90 per cent of exports, and
very often more than half to two-thirds of export value is accounted
for by one single commodity. This naturally makes both the balance of
payments and the domestic real economy extremely vulnerable to fluctuations
in output and price of this one good or group of goods.
Despite this dismal performance of primary commodities, the overall
terms of trade of all developing countries does not show such a negative
tendency, as will be clear from Charts 4 and 5. This is actually because
of the degree of diversification out of primary into manufactured exports
that was achieved by certain developing countries, such as the previously
named "dragons" of East and Southeast Asia as well as India
and some Latin American industrialisers. However, such trade and production
diversification is precisely what is now under threat in some countries
where it had proceeded quite substantially, and is further constrained
in less developed countries where it had not gone very far.
In regions where no such
process of export diversification was evident, such as Sub-Saharan Africa,
not only did terms of trade deteriorate very substantially, but this
also had very large negative effects on real national income. Chart
8 shows this, in terms of more than 10 per cent decline in terms of
trade over just two years 1997 and 1998, and an effect of this alone
on income amounting to 2.7 per cent of GDP.
The reason all this is
particularly worrying is that primary commodity prices are not expected
to recover very much in the medium term. Charts 6 and 7 show one set
of projections by the World Bank for oil and non-oil prices until 2001.
What is interesting is that despite the huge falls of the previous years,
prices will not increase much and are not even likely to regain their
levels of the mid-1990s. And this is notwithstanding the much-vaunted
"recovery" in East Asia which is supposed to increase world
demand for primary commodities once again.
One reason for this
is that in the current slump, except in the case of oil, producers/traders
of primary commodities have been reluctant to reduce output to limit
or reverse the fall in price. rather they have chosen the option of
increasing the level of stocks held (aided by relatively low interest
rates) and this has meant a fairly large overhang of inventories. Stocks
of metals such as copper and aluminium are at record levels; grain stockpiles
held by the major exporters have more than doubled over just three years;
sugar stocks are also reaching unprecedented levels.
Thus low prices now reflect more than the usual cyclical features. They
are now characterised by severe overcapacity in a situation of generally
sluggish world demand for such goods. It is clear that they are unlikely
to bring much joy to exporters in the medium term.
This is important, because this means the eradication of the hopes which
characterised the Uruguay Round of trade talks, that more liberal trade
would lead to higher prices for developing country exporters of primary
commodities. Instead, what we witness is low prices and overproduction,
in a situation where competitive pressure and the need to push out more
exports have made these commodities even greater sources of volatility
and vulnerability in domestic economies.