Forward
trading has a long history in the country, but it has never been a matter
of much public concern. Till recently, that is. When the search for explanations
for the increase in the prices of food began a few months back, some observers
turned their attention to the massive increase in forward and futures
trading in commodities. What emerged was revealing.
According to Bloomberg, quoting the Forward Markets Commission, volumes
on the National Commodity Exchange, which trades futures contracts in
48 commodities, reached $226 billion in the year ended March 31, 2006.
That was more than the $184 billion of shares traded on the Mumbai stock
exchange in the same period. Forward and futures trading had been promoted
on the ground that it helped traders deal with market uncertainty by hedging
their transactions, and stabilized prices for the final producers. However,
the surge in futures trading could not be explained by pure hedging requirements,
and obviously reflects an increase in speculative activity.
Leaders of the Left parties saw in this speculation an explanation for
the spike in food prices. Their view was endorsed by Sonia Gandhi, who
reportedly told a meeting of Congress Parliamentary Party members in early
August: ''The prime minister and I had a meeting with our chief ministers.
They were unanimous that forward trading, particularly in wheat, has had
an adverse impact and called for a more effective regulatory framework
to deal with speculation.'' As a result of these interventions, the government
has now decided to amend the Forward Contracts (Regulation) Act 1952 (FCRA)
and strengthen the regulatory powers of the Forward Markets Commission
(FMC). What form those amendments will take is yet to be seen.
Forward contracts have historically been a feature of commodity markets,
partly because while the demands of actual users of many commodities is
continuous across the year, supplies come into the market at specified
points in time such as harvest time. Producers of commodities have to
make production decisions based on expectations of the price that they
would receive when the output arrives, and purchasers of commodities as
inputs or final goods must make judgments of the availability and cost
of the commodity at different points of time during the year. To guard
against price volatility and uncertainty in production and availability,
sellers and buyers often enter into forward contracts, specifying the
quantity, quality and price of the commodity they would deliver for sale
or acquire for purchase at a pre-decided date in the future.
It should be clear that forward contracts are means of hedging against
the risk of price volatility or uncertainty of supply. But hedgers cannot
function without the presence of speculators. If the market is restricted
to hedgers, who are actual producers or users of the commodity, the volume
of many contracts could be so low that on some days a trade cannot occur,
because a buyer cannot find a seller or vice versa. This is where the
speculators step in. They buy or sell in forward trades, not with the
intention of actually making or taking delivery, but with the idea of
transferring the concerned contract to an actual producer or user at a
profit. They can therefore, buy and sell a large number of contracts,
enabling the hedger to transfer risk with ease by injecting liquidity
into the system. But the moment speculation begins, there is the risk
that prices could be manipulated to move consistently in one direction
for significant periods of time, inflicting losses on some and gains for
the others.
Forward contracts, however, are cumbersome. It requires intending sellers
of specific quantities of specific quality at specified times to find
the appropriate number of buyers. This entails costs of search and inspection.
Further, since there is no centralized market or exchange where the contract
is drawn up, prices tend to vary and there is uncertainty about delivery.
It is for this reason that futures contracts were evolved.
Futures contracts differ from forward contracts in important respects.
Futures contracts are standardized contracts to buy or sell a standard
quantity of a standard quality of a commodity. These are traded in exchanges,
through brokers, with no need for the buyer and seller to meet and negotiate.
An important feature is that a contract need not be settled by actual
delivery. It can be matched by an offsetting contract taken by the buyer
or seller, and the two can be squared at any point at some gain or loss.
The administration of the exchange guarantees that contracts would be
settled, and requires traders to pay up margins to cover ongoing losses,
if any, to secure the viability of the exchange. To avoid paying margins,
traders can buy an option to offer or acquire a contract at some specified
future date. If the option is not exercised, because price movements are
contrary to expectations, the loss is restricted to the premium paid to
hold the option and the transaction costs of acquiring it.
The existence of futures contracts allows sellers or buyers to hedge against
risk by buying offsetting futures contracts that would protect them against
losses if the market moves against them. But hedging is not the sole driver
of futures markets. The emergence of futures contracts and derivatives
such as options in commodity markets, allows the implicit trade in commodities
to be many multiples of the explicit trade. The volume of implicit trade
is only restricted by the extent of liquidity in the market, whereas the
volume of explicit trade is limited by the actual availability of the
commodity from different sources. If liquidity in the market fed by speculation
is high, prices in futures markets can move in ways that could influence
the spot or ready prices at which the commodity is actually sold.
However, if the futures market is predicting a rise in the price of a
commodity say, and those holding stocks of the commodity want to benefit,
the actual supply and demand for the commodity must be such that spot
prices can move in ways that reflect that trend. This depends upon the
ability of stockholders to regulate supply in an appropriate manner. Three
things are necessary for this: (i) the government should not have large
stocks in its hands to dampen spot prices; (ii) the private trade must
have stocks to deliver and the capacity to hold on to it till such time
prices rise; and (iii) there should be no danger that cheap imports could
be resorted to, as and when domestic prices rise.
It transpires that liberalization of the trade in agricultural commodities
within the country had ensured the realization of the first two of these
conditions. Liberalization has involved the removal of controls on the
inter-state movements of agricultural commodities (from surplus to deficit
regions); the liberalization of rules relating to the operation of private
traders and agribusiness firms, which has brought in large players into
commodity markets; and some weakening of the procurement programme of
the government as a prelude to the dismantling of the PDS.
According to reports, private firms such as Cargill India, Adani Exports,
ITC and the Australian Wheat Board have together purchased as much as
30 lakh tonnes of wheat this year. While some of this is for conversion
into processed goods in their own facilities, a significant part is for
resale at a profit. Private firms have also been involved in trading in
other commodities. This indicates that large trading firms have cornered
supplies of many commodities at prices higher than minimum support price
offered by the government.
One consequence of these trends has been a decline in government stocks
from record levels and a rise in stockholding by the private trade for
speculative purposes. Thus the government has managed to procure only
92 lakh tonnes of wheat this year as compared with 147 lakh tonnes last
year. As a result, wheat stocks with the government stood at 93 lakh tonnes
on June 1, having declined continuously when compared with the level on
the same date of the last few years, starting at 413 lakh tones on June
1, 2002. Overall, food stocks with the government stood at 223 lakh tonnes
on June 1, 2006, close to a third of their peak level of 648 lakh tonnes
on June 1, 2002. These declines are far more than warranted by trends
in production, indicating that private trade has managed to corner a significant
volume of stocks.
These developments on the availability front have provided the basis for
speculative trading in commodity futures. Trading on India's commodity
exchanges totaled $460 billion in the year ended March 31, a fourfold
jump from the year before. There is sufficient ground to believe that
the recent surge in the prices of certain essentials, including wheat,
seems to be driven by such speculation.
This has been aided by a policy of freely allowing exchange-based trading
in futures and commodity derivatives. Commodity futures trading had been
banned for much of the post-Independence period, so that the commodity
derivatives market was virtually non-existent. At present, the country
has 3 national level electronic exchanges and 21 regional exchanges for
trading commodity derivatives. As many as eighty (80) commodities have
been allowed for derivatives trading.
The process of liberalization began after the Government set up a Committee
under the Chairmanship of K. N. Kabra in 1993 to examine the role of futures
trading in the context of liberalization and globalization. The Kabra
Committee, while cautious, recommended allowing futures trading in 17
selected commodity groups. It also recommended strengthening of Forward
Markets Commission (FMC) and amendments to Forward Contracts (Regulation)
Act, 1952.
However, this cautious approach was dropped in 1998, which saw the adoption
of a major reform package involving the FMC and the Exchanges, spurred
by a World Bank-funded grant. The reform included the introduction of
futures trading in edible oils, oilseeds and their cakes, which was a
turning point in the development of commodity futures contracts in India.
The National Agricultural Policy announced by the Government in the year
1999 declared that the Government will enlarge the coverage of the futures
market to minimize the wide fluctuations in commodity prices, as also
for hedging their risk. In the Budget for 2002-03, the Finance Minister
announced expansion of futures and forward trading to cover all agricultural
commodities. These initiatives have paved the way for the speculative
price increases that have forced the government to import as much as 39
lakh tonnes of wheat and ease imports of other commodities, which can
have damaging consequences in the long run. It is perhaps time to reverse
some of these policies, starting with a ban on forward trading in essential
commodities.
|