The
UPA government has committed to legislating an employment guarantee
for both rural and urban areas, which would ensure at least 100 days
of public employment for a member of poor and lower middle class households.
A start is to be made with a Rural Employment Guarantee Act, to be implemented
first in 150 districts and then extended to the entire country within
five years.
These commitments of the government are absolutely essential, both politically
and economically. The collapse in employment growth over the past decade
was a major contributor to the popular dissatisfaction with the previous
government, and all the political parties involved in the new government
had promised a redirection of economic policy to increase employment
and revive agriculture.
However,
even before the proposed legislation can be tabled in Parliament, there
is already strong opposition to it both within and outside government.
The criticisms that are being levelled are broadly on three grounds.
First, that the public resources required for implementing the EGA are
so large that the entire scheme is simply unsustainable, and in any
case the government at present can simply not afford it. Second, that
in any case such public money is better spent directly on large infrastructural
investments which would directly assist economic growth. Third, that
this is just throwing money away because of the large leakages in the
delivery system, which ensure that the intended beneficiaries will receive
only a small proportion of the money that is spent.
None of these criticisms is valid, despite some superficial plausibility.
Consider the first argument, that such a programme of guaranteeing employment
would cost too much for the government to bear. Obviously, it is difficult
in advance to predict exactly how many people would avail themselves
of the opportunity to work at some pre-established wage. There are various
estimates of the total cost, ranging from Rs. 25,000 crore to Rs. 45,000
crore per year to cover all of rural India. This is only between 0.7
and 1.5 per cent of the GDP, a trifling proportion. Such an amount can
be raised quite easily if there is sufficient political will.
India's central tax-GDP ratio (at less than 10 per cent) is currently
among the lowest in the developing world. Furthermore, it has been declining
for two decades, especially after neo-liberal economic reforms were
introduced in 1991. If the tax-GDP ratio of the central government were
simply brought back to the level of 1991, that would release another
2.5 per cent of GDP, which is more than enough to cover the entire amount
estimated for the proposed EGA, and still leave enough to pay for the
school meals programme across India.
Suppose the government is even more ambitious, and tries to raise the
tax-GDP ratio to that prevailing in Sub-Saharan Africa. That would release
more than 7 per cent of GDP, that is around Rs. 210,000 crore, which
is more than enough to finance all the developmental goals of the government.
So the perceived shortage of resources only reflects political unwillingness
to increase tax collection. Similarly, choosing to spend in areas other
than public employment generation also reflects a certain political
choice. For example, the government has already made it clear that it
will continue with the programme of nuclear weaponisation, which is
potentially very dangerous and also incredibly expensive, yet there
are no murmurs about the cost to the country involved in such expenditure.
In any case, there is no reason to fear increased public spending on
employment generation in the current context. There is substantial macroeconomic
slack in the form of excess capacity and large-scale unemployment and
underemployment, excess foreign exchange reserves and more than comfortable
food grain stocks. This means that more public spending is not likely
to be inflationary. Instead, it will generate much more economic activity
(and therefore also tax revenues) over time.
Therefore there is a strong case for substantial allocation of resources
for an employment programme. If resources cannot immediately be raised
through taxation, the programme can be financed through government borrowing
from the Reserve Bank of India (that is, deficit financing) instead
of from commercial banks, since that involves a much lower rate of interest
and in any case will not be any more inflationary.
This gives rise to the second argument – that even if the government
can afford to spend more now, such spending is best directed towards
large-scale capital-intensive infrastructure projects that the private
sector cannot or will not take up. It is argued that these will generate
more growth in the long run by easing supply bottlenecks.
This argument involves the fallacy of treating different types of expenditure
as necessarily substitutes rather than complementary. It also ignores
the crucial point that the Indian economy at this point must move towards
employment-led growth, since the past pattern of jobless growth is neither
economically desirable nor politically acceptable.
Most significantly, the point is that employment generation schemes,
if imaginatively conceived and properly implemented, can have very substantial
effects in terms of creating conditions for much higher levels of economic
activity and therefore growth, especially in the rural areas. To begin
with, there are the obvious multiplier effects of such spending. Wage
employment puts money in the hands of rural workers who are therefore
able to spend on basic consumer items, which will play an important
role in reviving local markets and rural industries. Since the entire
rural economy is in severe depression, such a positive effect is very
important, since it will create conditions for the further expansion
of private economic activity in rural India.
In addition, since the EGA will ensure public employment of a certain
level for a continuous period, it will allow local authorities to plan
to and put such labour to the best possible use. These uses can include
creating durable rural assets, water management and watershed development,
activities designed to increase land productivity and create more sustainable
agriculture with less chemical use, providing essential public services
such as sanitation and mobilisation for health purposes, providing mid-day
meals in school, and the like. All these not only ensure a better quality
of life for rural residents, they also have critical effects in enabling
future economic growth on a sustainable basis.
The third criticism is probably the strongest, since it is found even
among those who otherwise welcome an employment guarantee for the poor.
This is the argument that corruption and weak delivery systems will
ensure that the target population will get very little of the benefits,
and that the money will be badly used or effectively wasted. Obviously,
there are serious grounds for concern on this score, since even the
bravest supporter of governments at state and central level would not
argue that there are no leakages in government expenditure.
But there are two reasons why this should not deter an Employment Guarantee
Act. The first is that, while obviously corruption and wastage cannot
be condoned and must be minimised, the legal commitment to spend in
rural areas would rectify some of the large increase in urban-rural
disparity that occurred in the past decade. Even if there are leakages,
money spent inside the rural economy will play a positive role because
of its multiplier effects. The second reason is even more important.
It is now quite well known that the only real check on leakage and corruption
is community participation, empowerment and control. But this is precisely
what the Act proposes, using panchayati raj institutions. It is interesting
that those who oppose this Act are also generally opposed to the Right
to Information Act. They would accept higher spending if politically
necessary, but oppose enactment of fiscal commitment or political empowerment.
More than anything else, it is this attitude to public spending and
to economic rights that encourages the corruption and leakages which
they then piously decry.
So it is clear that the prevailing criticisms of the EGA do not hold
water and that the benefits of such legislation and such expenditure
would greatly outweigh the potential difficulties. This being said,
there are still problems with the legislation as it is currently being
conceived. One problem is with the definition of household. Women's
groups such as AIDWA have pointed out that the current provision restricting
the scheme to one member per household is problematic not only because
of its gender implications, but because the poor often are forced into
large households by the cost of living. It is much better to provide
an open scheme whereby any rural adult, male or female, is eligible
for such a guarantee.
The second problem is the restriction of the guarantee to 100 days.
This, and the earlier provision, reflect the fear that otherwise the
requirement of employment would become too large of the government to
handle. But the Maharashtra EGS experience shows that this need not
be the case. In any case, the administrative costs of working out 100
days per households may turn out to be quite large, and could be done
away with in a more open-ended scheme. This would of course have a beneficial
upward effect on rural wages in general, which may be why some sections
oppose it so strenuously.
Ultimately, the EGA is a major move in the right direction. It can provide
much-needed employment for the rural poor and can become the basis for
the necessary regeneration of the rural economy, without which sustainable
aggregate growth is not possible.