Increasingly
it looks as if the UPA government will try to introduce an Employment
Guarantee Act in the near future. It is obviously equally incumbent
upon it to substantially increase the resources that are to be made
available for employment schemes, especially in the rural areas. Both
of these were positive promises of the CMP, and it is necessary to hold
the government to these promises.
However,
thus far the bureaucratic moves in this direction have been characterised
by remarkable lack of ambition. At the moment, the declared plan to
begin to implement the employment guarantee in 150 backward districts
is being thought of in government circles in a very limited way. The
proposal apparently is to combine some existing schemes, shift money
from some other schemes to this one, and generally try to implement
the scheme in these districts with only a modest additional outlay of
resources. The argument being made is that this is necessitated by the
lack of increased budgetary allocation under this head and the need
to accommodate other demands which also reflect promises made in the
CMP, such as increased public expenditure on health and education.
In fact, in the mainstream media the bogeys are already being raised
that all this is going to cost far too much and is therefore not feasible;
that the costs of a universal employment guarantee scheme alone would
be so great that it would turn out to be simply impossible to sustain;
and that this may imply greater tax burden on the middle classes who
are already suffering higher rates of consumer price inflation.
While these are predictable responses, they reflect a deeper urge among
the elite and those among the middle class who have benefited from the
previous decade of inequalising policies, to avoid a change in economic
policy direction. In fact, each of these arguments can be effectively
countered. In particular, it can be shown that the employment guarantee
scheme is neither likely to be as expensive over time as many of the
projections suggest, nor as difficult for the public exchequer to finance.
Consider first of all the estimated cost of the employment guarantee.
Suppose that it is first of all only for rural areas, and confined only
to 100 days per person (although this is clearly not ideal). On the
basis of the available data on rural labour force, per capita consumption
and the like, it may be estimated that some 35 to 40 per cent of the
rural labour force would be the maximal number of those seeking such
employment. Many of them in turn would not necessarily require such
work for the full 100 days. Therefore let us assume that a maximum of
100 million people would require such work through the public employment
programme.
If only one adult per household (rather than any adult who wants it)
is provided with such work at the minimum wage, then the number of people
eligible for such work would be even less, at between 35 and 40 million.
This is in fact what the CMP has promised, but it is certainly less
than desirable, and in fact the preferable option should be to try to
provide such wage employment to any adult, male or female, who wishes
to avail of the opportunity.
At the minimum wage (which can be taken at a national average of around
Rs. 60 per day) and with 2:1 ratio of wages to material costs, the cost
per worker comes to Rs. 9,000 per year. This generates total costs of
between Rs. 31,000 crores and Rs. 36,000 crores per annum. Remember
that this is likely to be a maximal estimate, since actual demand may
be much less and may actually decline over time (for reasons that are
explained below).
This may be why one estimate currently circulating in official circles
pegs the estimated cost at Rs. 25,000 crores. If half of the wage component
is provided in foodgrain, the financial cost comes down even further,
and there are some implicit public savings since this would reduce the
food stock carrying costs of the Food Corporation of India.
But how is even this amount of resources to be mobilised? This is the
question that is most frequently asked by critics of the programme.
Recently, the Minister for Rural Development, Shri Raghuvansh Prasad
Singh, suggested that there could be another cess on taxes (similar
to the education cess of 2 per cent imposed in the last Budget) to raise
some of the money. This was immediately seized upon by the media to
warn of the pressure that was going to put upon ''ordinary citizens''
by such taxation measures.
It is true that a cess on taxes is less than ideal as a method of resource
mobilisation, since it is essentially regressive in nature and affects
the prices of commodities purchased by the poor. But in fact there are
numerous other ways of raising tax revenues which can be considered
quite easily. The turnover tax on stock market transactions, which caused
share brokers to make a very vocal protest, was one such measure. Such
a tax has a lot of potential, but unfortunately the Finance Minister
caved in to brokers’ pressure and reduced the spread and rate of taxation,
so that much less revenue will be earned from it.
At the same time, the capital gains tax was removed and has not been
re-imposed despite the dilution of the turnover tax. There is no reason
not to impose a capital gains tax, which simply takes a small share
of the proceeds of essentially unproductive activities. There is a lot
of scope for broadening the scope and coverage of taxes on services
as well. India currently has one of the lowest tax to GDP ratios in
the world, which is hardly justified even at this relatively low level
of per capita income.
But even raising more tax revenues - necessary as it is in the medium
term - is not an essential prerequisite for providing more public resources
to critical areas such as the employment guarantee programme. One of
the simplest ways of generating financial resources - simply printing
more money - appears to have been forgotten in the general debate about
finding the money for government spending at the present time.
The traditional argument against printing money to cover public deficits
- of deficit financing - was that it would cause inflation. That was
based on a simplistic notion of what constitutes money supply, which
even monetarist economists would blush to admit to nowadays. However,
the basic idea - that any deficit that causes expenditure to increase
beyond output would be inflationary - is also only valid in a world
where supply bottlenecks prevent output from rising as demand rises.
In an economy that is in India’s current macroeconomic situation, with
foodgrain surpluses, large foreign exchange reserves and excess capacity
in industry, there is no reason to expect that increased public spending
would be inflationary; rather, it would generate more economic growth.
The basic point is that such deficit-financed government spending will
lead to a rise in output which will generate the very savings necessary
to back it up. This makes arguments of ''crowding out'' both irrelevant
and inapplicable.
More importantly, if the spending is directed towards rural works programmes
or rural public services, for example, it would generate the most desirable
kind of growth, which would have large multiplier effects, increase
rural economic activity and therefore create more rural jobs indirectly.
This in turn means that the initial spending on rural employment programmes,
if it is done properly, will have multiplier effects that increase the
availability of other, non-public, income generating activities.
Over time, that would mean the employment generation in the rural economy
would improve, and also create more employment diversification in the
countryside. Therefore, spending on employment programmes would have
positive effects upon total employment that are far greater than the
direct effect in terms of jobs paid for by the public exchequer. In
the most ideal scenario, an effective employment guarantee would create
conditions making itself superfluous over time, in that it would indirectly
generate many more job opportunities in the rural economy.
Of course this is the best possible scenario, but it should be apparent
that even when there are large leakages from the system (whether through
corruption or inefficiency) money that is spent in the rural areas is
not entirely wasted because of the positive multiplier effects that
it generates.
Of course it is important to improve delivery systems and devise methods
of making such expenditure more effective, as well as making the managing
institutions more accountable and responsive to local people. But the
huge advantage generated simply by the fact of higher spending in the
rural economy, should not be lost sight of.
This also means that money spent on rural employment schemes will eventually
pay for itself, and only the more short-sighted of macroeconomists,
with a very short time horizon, would fail to realise this. So the very
positing of the question: ''where is the money?'' is misleading especially
in this case.