What
seemed inevitable for almost two decades, finally seems imminent. The mid-November
Sino-US agreement over the terms on which the US would support China's entry
into the 135-member WTO, paves the way for the quick accession of that country
into the world trading arrangement. Needless to say, the Chinese government
would have to win the support of many other members as well. Under the rules
governing the WTO, where voting rights are distributed on the one-nation,
one-vote principle and which follows the convention of taking decisions by
consensus, the general council or a ministerial conference has to approve
a membership treaty drafted after agreement with all members on the terms
of accession. This requires, in principle, bilateral deals with all member
countries. While quite a few countries had virtually unconditionally backed
China's request for membership, 12 formal bilateral deals have been inked
so far and negotiations are still open with another 28 countries, including
the European Union. However, for political reasons, agreement with the US
was considered a major stumbling block. With that block having been cleared,
full agreement is widely expected to follow soon, even if not in time for
the Seattle ministerial meet at the end of November.
To
most China watchers, this outcome seemed inevitable, once it was clear that
the Chinese economic reform which began in 1978 would remain in place. This
view was buttressed by the fact that, despite China's exclusion from the formal
world trading arrangement during the 1980s and 1990s, exports constituted
a major plank of its growth strategy under reform. The share of merchandise
trade in China's aggregate product rose from 9.2 per cent in 1978 to 16.8
per cent in 1984 and more than 20 per cent in the mid-1990s.
This
dependence on trade implied a growing engagement of world markets. China's
share of world merchandise exports which stood at between 0.7 and 0.8 per
cent during the 1970s, rose to 1.4 per cent in 1983 and stood at 2.9 per cent
in 1996. In that year, China's share was higher than that of other leading
developing country exporters like South Korea (2.5 per cent), Singapore (2.4
per cent), Taiwan (2.2 per cent) and Mexico (1.8 per cent). With exports constituting
the goal of an important segment of domestic economic activity and China's
presence in international markets increasing, it no more appeared sensible
for China to be vulnerable to unilateral trade policy responses and tenuous
bilateral arrangements. The dangers were epitomised by the debates which surrounded
the annual exercise since 1974 in which the US Congress had to ratify continuing
a normal trading relationship with China.
Not
surprisingly, China declared in 1986 that it would like to be part of the
multilateral framework governing world trade. The fact that China's accession
is finally in sight only 13 years later is not primarily due to its own recalcitrance.
There have been occasions when China has on many trade-related issues been
willing to go further in the direction of liberalisation than developing countries
participating in the multilateral trading arrangement. In fact, in the dispute
over patent regimes during the later stages of the negotiations that led up
to the Uruguay Round agreement, China's willingness to compromise at a bilateral
level was quoted to smother developing-country opposition and buttress developed-country
positions. What held back the final agreement were complex political and economic
compulsions in the developed countries, especially the US.
That
such compulsions played a role is clear from the fact that as recently as
April, President Clinton turned down terms offered by China in return for
US support for her entry, which were no different from those underlying the
mid-November agreement. Those terms were by no means limited.
To
start with, it involves a substantial degree of liberalisation of trade. China's
average import tariffs are to be reduced by almost 5 percentage points or
23 per cent from 22.1 per cent to 17 per cent. Tariffs on some farm products
exported by the US are to be reduced sharply to 15 per cent. And tariffs on
automobiles, currently ranging up to 100 per cent are to be subject to a "front-loaded"
reduction to 25 per cent over a six-year period.
Secondly,
the package offers a number of new concessions for foreign firms and investors.
For example, international automobile manufacturers and banks would be allowed
to offer consumer loans for car purchases, which is a crucial concession given
the high price of automobiles in China relative to incomes. Foreign manufacturers
will also be allowed to distribute their own products imported from abroad
and not be forced to rely on domestic distributors. Above all, foreign firms
are to be provided an important role in the emerging and rapidly growing telecommunications
sector (including internet). The agreement provides for foreign firms to hold
49 per cent of the equity in local ventures for a period of two years and
50 per cent subsequently.
The
third area in which major concessions have been offered is the financial sector.
Thus far foreign banks were allowed to offer their services to foreign companies
operating in China. But under the terms of the agreement they would be allowed
to offer their services to Chinese firms two years after their entry, providing
loans, undertaking currency transactions and servicing their other banking
requirements. Limits on the insurance business undertaken by foreign insurance
companies are also to be gradually dismantled and they are to be allowed to
increase the number and expand the size of their branches as well as enter
new areas such as property. Market access is to be eased and enlarged for
foreign legal and accounting firms as well. Finally foreign brokerage houses
and mutual funds are to be allowed to form joint ventures with Chinese companies,
holding 33 per cent initially and a possible 49 per cent subsequently.
In
return for these substantial concessions, the US has agreed to support China's
claim to WTO membership. But it has not offered very much else. In the contentious
area of textiles, which is a major item in the Chinese export basket, quotas
are to be phased out only by 2005. The US has also reserved for itself the
right to respond in protectionist fashion to what it sees as import surges
in the US market for a period of ten years, and to similarly respond to "dumping"
for a period of 15 years. The experience under the Uruguay Round so far points
to the ease with which such clauses can be converted into protectionist devices
by developed countries.
The
willingness of China, an important developing country exporter which has been
struggling to join the formal multilateral trade framework, to make these
compromises is to an extent understandable. What is less clear is why the
US which, for political reasons, was earlier unwilling to accept even these
terms, has suddenly come round to accepting an agreement which, according
to some reports is not as good as the terms which were on offer and were rejected
in April. Moreover, given the impending Presidential elections and the strong
opposition to Chinese entry among the trade unions, the timing of the agreement
is indeed surprising. The AFL-CIO has vowed to fight the deal, both because
it threatens American jobs as well as goes against America's "democratic principles
and most cherished values". And some local business interests, including the
textile lobby have also sharply attacked the agreement.
If
yet the Clinton administration has chosen to go through with it, it is possibly
because of a strategic concern. It is indeed pointless not integrating an
emerging economic power like China into current and future negotiations on
the world trading system. But, more importantly, the willingness of China
to make crucial concessions in areas like foreign investment and the financial
sector could be an important source of pressure on recalcitrant developing
countries unwilling to agree to start negotiations on investment and services,
as part of a new Round. That could possibly explain the willingness to conclude
an agreement on terms rejected only recently, in time for the ministerial
meet at Seattle. As in the case of patents at the time of the Uruguay Round,
China is implicitly being held up as a model of a developing country with
a reasonable negotiating position.
Matters
of course are far more complex. Given the political and legal structure in
China, and autonomy of local governments especially after the reform, accepting
an agreement is a far cry from implementing its provisions. Despite China's
early acceptance of strong patent rights regulations earlier than many developing
countries, not only is reverse engineering the rule among Chinese firms, but
international firms detecting patent or copyright violations are rarely in
a position to challenge them and get the government to initiate action.
In
fact, this time around, the consequences of implementing the provisions of
the agreement relating to trade liberalisation can be extremely damaging,
especially for the state owned enterprises primarily created during the pre-reform
years. There were 118,000 such firms in China in 1998. Though the contribution
of these state-owned enterprises (SOEs) to China's industrial output had fallen
from over 75 per cent in 1978 (when economic reform began) to less than 35
per cent in 1995, this was not so much due to the shrinkage of this sector
as to the expansion in the rest of the industrial sector consisting of the
collective enterprises, the individually owned enterprises, wholly foreign
owned firms, and foreign joint ventures.
What
is significant is that even now the SOEs dominate or even monopolise their
chosen areas of operation, which are the capital-intensive, heavy and basic
goods industries characterised by lumpy investments and long gestation lags.
The significance of the state-owned enterprises comes through in other ways
as well. For example, they still constitute the principal source of employment
in urban China. In 1995, seven out of ten urban workers were employed in state
firms. Such employment does not ensure just a wage, but a range of welfare
benefits such as housing, medical care and retirement benefits. Further, state-owned
enterprises constitute the primary source of tax revenue for government. In
1995, SOEs produced only 35 per cent of China's industrial output, but contributed
71 per cent of government revenues. Thus, it is not only directly that the
SOEs contribute to the government's governance and welfare responsibilities,
but indirectly, by providing the latter with the wherewithal to finance its
own expenditures.
Trade
liberalisation, which would subject these units to competition, and financial
sector reform, which would make it extremely difficult for them to access
the credit so crucial to their survival, mainly threatens these firms. Thus,
the terms of WTO entry, if implemented, could spell unemployment and erode
standards of living. According to the official Xinhua News Agency, China's
Labour Minister Zhang Zuoji stated in a report to the financial and economic
committee of the National People's Congress earlier this year, that more than
three million workers in China's state-owned enterprises are expected to lose
their jobs this year. They would join the six to seven million people who,
having been retrenched from state firms, were yet to find new jobs. Zhang
noted that, while China would need 24.5 billion yuan ($2.95 billion) this
year to provide basic living expenses to laid-off workers, the amount currently
available was only 19.5 billion yuan. This problem of inadequate support is
bound to intensify if China resorts to massive trade and financial sector
liberalisation involving partial retrenchment or closure of public sector
units, since there were an estimated 113 million urban workers employed by
state owned firms in 1995.
It
is for this reason that it is hard to believe that China would go ahead with
the kind of liberalisation it has promised on a range of fronts. In fact,
there are many China watchers who are sceptical. For example the Financial
Times quotes Gordon Chang, a lawyer in a Beijing firm, who argues that: "If
it (China) really follows through on the agreement, the changes are going
to be little short of revolutionary. This leads me to believe that the agreement
is not going to be implemented as announced."
In
the circumstances the view that all developing countries should give in to
a more liberal and unequal global order just as China has done may be completely
misplaced. China's giving in may be more rhetorical than real. And the competitive
threat to developing countries from China, which has been intense in the past,
is unlikely to increase after China's entry into the WTO.
Unfortunately
misplaced views about the implications of China's entry are being aired in
India as well, in defence of the position that India should 'learn from China'
and not insist on a review of the Uruguay Round and raise too many objections
to a new Millenium Round with a far-reaching agenda. But as in the case of
developed-country spokespersons, this is just one more ruse to push through
their own agenda.
|