To
many today the question is not whether the Eurozone would survive,
but how long it would. A crisis that started in the European periphery,
transiting through Ireland and Portugal, had gathered momentum when
it reached Spain and Greece. What Ireland and Portugal had signalled
was that sovereign debt, or the debt owed by governments, was no longer
seen as being safe by definition. There were, of course, two features
characteristic of the debt owed by these countries. The first was
that it was not in a currency that was only their own, but rather
was that of a larger community of nations. The second was that it
was owed to large financial institutions, banks and non-bank financial
companies, which had bought into these government bonds on the expectation
that they were completely safe.
Government debt has conventionally been associated with near-zero
income and capital risk, since the interest was always expected to
be paid when due and the capital was always expected to be returned
wen the loan reaches maturity. But this expectation was partly based
on two presumptions. The first was that governments had not just the
right but also the capability to mobilise resources through taxation
to meet their commitments. The second was that when governments were
temporarily unable to mobilise the required tax revenues they could
borrow at will, if need be from the ''lender of last resort'', the
central bank, which would turn to the mint to obtain the needed currency
if required.
Both of these are proving difficult to realize in the Eurozone. A
feature of recent global developments has been a backlash against
the state that has taken the form of a tax revolt by the rich. Governments
have been under pressure to incentivise private savings and investment,
not by spending to create demand but by reducing the taxes paid out
of incomes and profits. This obviously meant that governments have
increasingly lost their ability to manage their finances by adjustments
on the revenue side, and are more dependent on spending cuts to rein
in their budgetary deficits or generate budgetary surpluses.
The second feature applicable to the Eurozone countries is that individual
countries have lost their ability to print at will more of their currency,
since the euro is governed by rule of the monetary union and is not
subject to the discretionary policy of individual central banks. This
implies that as and when budgetary deficits arise governments are
forced to finance those deficits by borrowing from the open market.
And ''the markets'' consisting of potential investors in government
bonds are neither required to buy into those bonds nor accept the
terms such as interest rates dictated by governments.
These changed features of the financial environment were not noticed
till such time as the markets ''perceived'' the level of borrowing
by individual governments as being acceptable. In recent years, however,
many governments have seen a huge increase in the volume of their
debt relative to GDP. Not all of this is due to ''profligate spending''.
In fact, in many countries debt has ballooned because of the expenditures
made by these government to ''bail-out'' a private financial system
in crisis as well as to stimulate economies experiencing recession
in the aftermath of the financial crisis. The resulting budget deficits
had to be financed with new borrowing. Private investors whose wealth
was being protected from excessive erosion by the government bail-out
of banks and non-bank financial companies and who were looking for
new safe avenues for investment, bought into the government bonds
that were issued to finance these expenditures. That increased their
exposure to public debt.
No objections were raised against deficit spending so long as the
purpose was to save private finance and protect the wealth holders.
But once such spending had occurred, resulting in an accumulation
of a large volume of debt, attention was focused on how the repayment
commitments associated with such debt were to be met. Governments,
it was argued, must cut spending through adoption of austerity measures
in order to generate the surpluses required for the purpose. If the
evidence was that governments were not doing this and increasing their
debt levels further, then the ''markets'' were either unwilling to
give them more credit or were willing to do so only at exorbitant
interest rates. In countries such as Greece, the interest rate on
public debt rose to levels far above that paid on German bonds, reflecting
the risk perceived in lending to those governments. When interest
rates rise sharply, the higher interest burden makes the spending
cuts needed to restore ''balance'' even greater. But spending cuts
affect growth and employment adversely, and therefore the level of
government revenues from taxation. This makes ''adjustment'' even
more difficult to ensure. Thus, the actual outcome is a spiral of
ever-increasing austerity, which becomes politically difficult to
impose.
A good example of how this plays out is Greece. Given the level of
its revenues, Greece needs access to credit to finance even unavoidable
expenditures like its salary and pension bills. But lenders are unwilling
to provide the needed credit unless the government adopts new austerity
measures that would adversely affect a population already burdened
with spending cuts and income losses. Austerity becomes a requirement
for a third reason, other than the refusal to tax and the inability
to mint currency. This is the unwillingness of big finance, which
had merrily lent to governments, to adequately share the ''adjustment
costs'' in a crisis substantially caused by them.
During the negotiations on burden sharing to resolve the crisis in
Greece, one stumbling block has been the fixing of the haircut or
loss banks must be required to accept on the loans they made to Greece.
According to the official view the haircut agreed upon has risen from
nil, to 20 per cent to as much as 50 per cent of loan value. But doubts
have been expressed about the veracity of the 50 per cent figure.
According to reports the offer made by the Institute of International
Finance, which represents the banking industry, involves the issue
of new bonds for which the current debt would be swapped. Those bonds
are to be lucrative, carrying a high 8 per cent interest rate and
conditions regarding additional annual payments if and when the Greek
economy recovers. But the current value of the future stream of incomes
has been calculated using a high ''discount rate'' of 12 per cent,
making the discounted value of the bonds about 50 per cent lower than
the debt being substituted.
If through these means finance manages to reduce its burden substantially,
the consequences would be extremely damaging for those not culpable
for the crisis in the first place. According to the Financial Times,
the austerity package agree upon in Greece involves spending cuts
and tax increases that would reduce the average post-tax income of
Greek citizens by €5,600 from its current level of €41,400 or by 14
per cent-which is almost double the cut imposed on citizens in Ireland
and Portugal after their crisis.
All this occurs because lenders have lost their confidence in the
ability of the Greek government to repay debt under a business as
usual scenario. It must be noted that many countries were accumulating
large volumes of debt without any such loss of the confidence. The
degree to which public debt grew varied significantly across countries
in the Eurozone: Finland sports a gross debt to GDP ratio of just
above 50 per cent, Germany and France of 83 and 87 per cent respectively,
Portugal and Ireland of 106 and 109 per cent and Italy and Greece
of 121 and 166 per cent respectively.
Countries with the highest debt-to-GDP ratios are the ones saddled
with austerity or experiencing a loss of confidence among creditors.
But it is not always the level of debt that triggers the loss of creditor-confidence.
Spain, with a relatively low 67 per cent is facing more difficulties
than many others. Besides the sheer level of debt, another factor
that could possible be influencing the level of confidence is the
rate at which the public debt to GDP ratio rises. More recently, ''confidence''
has been influenced by the rating of pubic debt of individual countries
by leading credit rating agencies, the timing of whose decisions is
difficult to explain.
Once a decline in confidence is triggered, the process described above
begins necessitating governments to adopt round after round of austerity,
until it is not politically sustainable. Consider Greece for example.
Realising that the severe austerity demanded by lenders would be difficult
to implement without popular support, Socialist Prime Minister George
Papandreou announced a referendum to win social sanction to proceed.
Since the voters would not have sanctioned such austerity the country
would possibly have had to step out of the Eurozone with unforeseen
consequences. What followed the announcement, therefore, was a furore
that forced a retraction of the referendum, the resignation of the
prime minister and the constitution of a national ''unity'' government
involving all major parties (headed by the ''technocrat'' Lucas Papademos),
which promised to implement the austerity measures. As of now it is
unclear how the government can implement the promised measures and
meet the fiscal targets it has been set.
On the other hand, with the difficulties faced by the Greek government
in meeting its payments commitments becoming clear, attention has
shifted to other countries with similar problems. These countries
are far more important in the Eurozone. Italy, with a gross debt to
GDP ratio of 121 per cent (as compared with Greece's 166 per cent)
has been the focus of attention. Though the government chose to voluntarily
adopt austerity measures, lenders were not convinced that the measures
were adequate. Creditors are now less inclined to provide additional
credit to the Italian government or are only willing to lend at very
high interest rates that the government could not bear. This is disastrous
for a country that is estimated to require at least €650 billion in
credit over the next three years. Italy is now on a slippery slope
to possible default. That would be disastrous for the Eurozone, since
Italy accounts for close to 17 per cent of its GDP.
What is needed is for the European central back to print money to
buy up government debt, for the Italian government to tax its rich
and for banks to be forced to take a large and real haircut. But there
is disagreement on each of the possibilities. All that has happened
is a change of government in Italy as well. Since Silvio Berlusconi
was seen as incapable of delivering the necessary austerity, he had
to make way for a government of technocrats. In sum, the crisis has
resulted in a series of changes in government in countries with high
debt levels, so as to facilitate the turn to austerity. But that as
noted is no solution to the crisis in the Eurozone.