Once
again international attention is focussed on trade negotiations, with
hectic parlays between groups of countries before the forthcoming WTO
Ministerial Meeting in Hong Kong. And once again it is clear that developing
countries are unlikely to get much relief or advantage from these talks,
either in terms of being allowed greater flexibility to provide some
protection to their own producers, or in terms of greater market access
to the markets of developed countries.
So it is worth asking the question:
why are developing countries so persistently unable to extract any advantage
from these international negotiations, despite their clear moral advantage,
their greater numerical strength, and even the greater unity across
some groups that they have recently displayed by forming pressure groups
like the G-20 and the Group of African countries?
Of course it is true that international power remains unequally distributed
and dramatically skews the balance between the core group of rich nations
(and the US in particular) and developing countries in general. But
that is only part of the problem. One basic weakness of developing countries,
and one that renders them so much less effective in international trade
negotiations, is the concern they all have with increasing market access
to the developed world, which stems from the obsession with exports
as the engine of growth. This in turn make developing country governments
so desperate that they are willing to offer various concessions and
accept problematic clauses that affect their own domestic producers,
in the hope of somehow achieving the export expansion that is now seen
as the key to the development project.
Across the developing world, the basic stimulus to economic growth is
now seen to come from increasing access to and getting larger shares
of the international market, rather than building up the domestic market.
Even in countries that have had large growth of imports as well and
therefore do not show large trade surpluses at present (such as China
and much of East Asia) the stimulus to growth still is seen to come
from exports. Since all countries except the US are playing this particular
game, it follows that the US economy remains the most important stimulus
not only to world trade but to world economic activity generally. Even
for countries like China, where exports to the US account for only around
one-fifth of total exports, this remains the driving force for the accumulation
which then generates such high rates of aggregate growth and in turn
high aggregate savings.
But this very obsession with export growth as the means to development
creates its own contradictions. It leads to heightened competitive pressure
(the famous race to the bottom) which reduces unit values of exports
even as export volumes may increase. It prompts technological changes
in export and import-competing industries which mean that new production
tends to generate less employment, and therefore have lower domestic
multiplier effects. In any case, all developing countries together cannot
really hope to increase their share of world markets unless they diversify
their ultimate export destinations. Most important, this strategy prevents
more sustainable and equitable patterns of economic expansion based
on the domestic market.
The problem has become quite evident in world trade patterns, where
the ''fallacy of composition'' is now widely acknowledged to be a real
problem for developing country exporters. Simply put, this is the problem
that, while it may be possible for a small developing country to increase
its exports substantially without significantly reducing world market
prices, this is not true for developing countries as a whole or for
groups of countries or even large individual countries.
This means that a rapid increase in the volume of ''developing country
exports'' (which are typically resource-intensive or labour-intensive)
is likely to be associated with prices falls and adverse changes in
terms of trade for such exporters. In extreme cases, it is even possible
to get ''immiserising growth'' through trade, of the kind that Jagdish
Bhagwati had described several decades ago - where the benefits of increased
export volumes are more than offset by terms of trade losses.
While immiserising growth may not yet have occurred, there is clear
evidence that the prices of the manufactured exports of developing countries
have been weakening relative to those of industrial countries, especially
for the less skill-intensive manufactured exports. A book summarising
research undertaken at UNCTAD over some years (''Developing countries
and world trade: Performance and prospects'', edited by Yilmaz Akyuz,
Zed Books and Third World Network 2003) provides empirical substantiation
of this.
This study notes that this means that the debate must shift from the
concern with the terms of trade of primary producers versus manufactured
goods producers, to one based on the underlying factors that affect
terms of trade and world market behaviour. Earlier it was generally
accepted that diversification and shifting to manufactured goods production
and export was the necessary advice for developing countries. The well-known
Prebisch-Singer argument stated that developing countries would face
long-term declines in terms of trade because primary products were demanded
less as incomes increased, and could be over-supplied.
But now, it appears that the problem relates not just to the goods but
to the nature of the trading countries, their technological capacity
and the extent of surplus labour. It seems that the labour-intensive
manufactured goods exported by developing countries (even those that
appear to be ''skill-intensive'' and ''technology-intensive'' but really
derive their advantage from being produced by cheaper labour) behave
in very similar ways. So a shift from primary product exports to labour-intensive
manufactured exports can fail to solve the problem, simply because too
many other developing countries are trying to do the same thing.
In fact, global competition for labour-intensive manufacturing activities
has risen sharply in the past few years precisely for this reason, and
this has meant that countries have significantly increased volumes of
exports without reaping much benefit in terms of the total value of
these exports going up. This is very important because it provides a
cautionary note for policy makers regarding the orientation of development
strategy and the potential adverse fallout of the export obsession.
In this context, domestic deflation in developing countries becomes
almost necessary to perpetuate the system which provides the current
pattern of growth. Developing countries that have trade surpluses, or
have capital inflows, are all trying to avoid currency appreciation
by holding more foreign exchange reserves with the central bank. And
these reserves are usually held in what is seen as the world’s safest
place, the US - in Treasury Bills or US securities. It is felt that
by fuelling the US economic expansion, this ensures a continuing market
for exports by the rest of the world. Paradoxically, the US economy
then emerges as the only engine of growth and all other countries are
obsessed with ensuring increases in net exports to the US as the means
for sustaining their own growth.
It should be noted that all this has very little to do with ''free trade''.
Internationally, ''free market'' principles are speedily abandoned by
the ruling powers whenever imperialist designs are thereby affected.
Thus, adherence to ''free trade'' by the US administration has been
uneven at best, essentially serving the interests of US large capital,
and unilateralism remains the most significant trade instrument for
the Bush regime. The ''free trade agreements'' the US signs with less
powerful countries force huge concessions upon them and provide major
protection for its own large companies, including agribusinesses. And
the lack of acceptance of genuine free trade principles in the WTO by
the US and the EU is only too well known.
In this context, the only way for developing countries to get out of
this trap is to stop thinking of exporting to the US as the only or
even dominant means of economic expansion, and consider other ways of
growth and diversification, based on the domestic market or on alternative
trade patterns, perhaps within other regional arrangements. This has
special significance for large economies with potentially huge internal
markets. Such a shift in policy emphasis would also provide an opportunity
to bring in the role of developmental states catering to the citizen’s
needs rather than to the needs of the international market. It might
even, by changing the terms of bargaining, bring about a better deal
for developing countries in international trade negotiations.
But most significantly of all, the obsession with export growth not
only denies current structures supporting neo-liberalism erode the possibility
of developmental states. It is worth remembering that the countries
that are currently lauded as ''success stories'' of globalisation -
especially China - retain the developmental role of the state in crucial
ways, which are denied to those countries that are more directly affected
by imperialist hegemony.