Now that the
economy is clearly in recession, it becomes more and more obvious to most
players that the government must move quickly to pump prime the system and
increase expenditure in order to revive economic activity. And indeed, the
other features of the economy at present – such as the existence of huge
surplus foodgrain stocks in the public sector and a comfortable level of
foreign exchange reserves – ensure that such moves would not be
inflationary but rather expansionary.
The present situation is one that calls so blatantly for Keynesian style
increased public expenditure, that even the Confederation of Indian
Industry (CII) which is anything but an advocate for more government
spending in most circumstances, has asked for it. Nevertheless, despite
the overwhelming arguments in favour of an expansionary fiscal stance at
this stage, neo-liberal economists who advise the government tend to
remain unmoved.
Thus the Prime Minister's
Economic Advisory Council has cautioned against using fiscal stimuli even
in this context. Recently it has actually been argued by some neoliberal
economists that fiscal deficits are disastrous not only because they
"crowd out" private investment through higher real interest rates, but
because they apparently lead to lower aggregate savings and investment
rates in the economy ! And therefore, curbing the fiscal deficit by
cutting state expenditure becomes the primary goal for such economists,
regardless of the state of aggregate demand in the economy.
There are several important fallacies in such an argument. One set of
fallacies relates to the actual effects of fiscal deficits in particular
economic contexts, as considered below. And another area of confusion
stems from the fact that the very processes of economic and financial
liberalisation which are advocated by such economists, are actually
responsible for worsening the fiscal position of the government.
Consider first of all the
effects of a fiscal deficit. It is typically argued that large deficits
create macroeconomic instability in the form of inflation or external
imbalance. But the size of the fiscal deficit, which shows the net demand
arising from the government, does not necessarily have anything to do
directly with such ‘instability', since both of these depend upon ex
ante excess aggregate demand. In fact, if there is a positive private
savings balance (that is, private savings is more than private investment)
then this would finance the public deficit. A classic example is that of
Italy, where until 1997 the government ran huge fiscal deficits amounting
to around 9 per cent of GDP for more than a decade, and this was entirely
financed within the country by the private sector's savings surplus in the
fast growing economy.
Secondly, while large revenue deficits (which reflect the excess of
current non-capital expenditures over current revenues) can be
problematic, there is nothing necessarily wrong with borrowing to meet
investment requirements. In fact, there is a strong case for a fiscal
deficit composed entirely of public capital investment, as long as the
social rate of return from such investment exceeds the rate of interest.
Thirdly, a reduction in the
revenue deficit, or in the fiscal deficit, can be brought about in a
number of different ways besides expenditure cuts, the most obvious method
being an increase in direct tax revenue. Indeed in any developing economy
where glaring poverty coexists with offensive opulence, increased revenue
from direct taxes is urgently called for anyway as a means of reducing
inequalities. But policies of liberalisation or the new-style economic
reforms invariably underplay or even completely disregard this avenue of
deficit reduction and emphasise cuts in investment and welfare
expenditures.
So the theory underlying such expenditure cuts is completely invalid. But
even apart from this, it is the case that the various economic measures
that are undertaken as part of the neoliberal "reform" agenda, actually
operate to worsen the fiscal deficits which are invoked to justify
expenditure cuts in the first place. There are several ways in which this
occurs.
First, since inviting direct
foreign investment becomes an overriding objective of economic policy, the
rates at which they are taxed gets reduced in competition with other
countries. This, for reasons of symmetry, means that direct tax rates on
the rich as a whole are lowered. Since customs duties are cut as part of
the import liberalisation package, and excise duties, again for reasons of
symmetry, cannot be raised as a consequence, indirect tax revenues too
suffer. This is aggravated by the sluggishness in output growth that cuts
in government expenditure may engender. Liberalisation has an adverse
impact on tax revenues for three reasons. First, since trade
liberalisation has as an important component the reduction of the maximum
and average rate of tariffs imposed on commodities, revenue trends can be
adversely affected even if liberalisation leads to an increase in the
import bill. Second, since liberalisation is expected to spur private
sector demand and encourage the growth of private industry, Finance
Ministers have through the liberalisation years provided a range of excise
duty concessions, to revive or spur demand in individual sectors. Finally,
with the liberalisation driven objective of improving private incentives
to save and invest, the government has been providing a range of direct
tax concessions as well.
It is not surprising, therefore, to find that the tax to GDP ratio in the
India economy fell over the decade of neoliberal reform from more than 11
per cent at the start to around 9 per cent at the close – an abysmally low
ratio by international standards.
While tax revenues cannot be
raised for lowering budget deficits, the higher real interest rates,
resulting in a larger interest burden on the government add to the
expenditure side. Increased interest rates on public sector borrowing are
typical results of the financial liberalisation process. Two features are
particularly significant in this process : first, various measures which
increase interest rates in the economy; and second the raising of norms on
the Statutory Liquidity Ratios and other such compulsory holding of
government securities, which forces the government to take recourse to
open market borrowing to finance deficits.
Thus this type of economic strategy, which aims to restrict the fiscal
profligacy of the State, in effect contains within itself processes which
work to aggravate further the fiscal situation, through lower taxes on the
rich and higher interest rates.
Overall, therefore, economic
reform has had damaging consequences for the fiscal position of the
central government. Nothing reveals this more than the fact that, through
the 1990s, while capital expenditures as a proportion of GDP have fallen
sharply and revenue expenditures net of interest payments have stagnated,
the government's effort to hold down the fiscal deficit has been
completely unsuccessful.
All this, of course, in no way undermines the basic Keynesian argument for
increased state expenditure. In a situation of unutilised capacity and low
demand, increased spending will generate positive multiplier effects which
will increase economic activity, reduce slack and thereby add to future
public tax revenues because of the economic growth that will result. So
all increased state expenditure does not necessarily mean higher public
deficit, since some of this will come back as higher tax revenues.
Then there is the issue that such expenditure, by
generating more economic activity and employment, would directly benefit
workers and small scale producers. However, failing to engage in such
expenditure simply benefits a small group of rentiers who are obsessed
with the chimera of controlling fiscal deficit and tries to pander to
their interests. And by allowing low levels of employment and economic
activity to persist, by allowing foodgrains to rot instead to going in for
public food for work schemes, by allowing valuable domestic manufacturing
assets to be run down because of lack of demand, by depressing the
incentives for technological change and productivity increases, this
strategy commits a major crime against the more general public interest.
|