Now
that the votes have been counted and we know which party has won how
many seats, it might be worthwhile reflecting on an intriguing possibility
put forward by two of our leading political scientists, Yogendra Yadav
and Suhas Palshikar. They argue that for all the vibrancy of our democracy
and high levels of participation, it might actually be much ado about
nothing because it matters so little as to which government comes
to power in Delhi.
In an article in a forthcoming book ‘Electoral Politics in India:
Lok Sabha Elections in 2004 and Beyond' (edited by Sandeep Shastri,
K.C. Suri and Yogendra Yadav), they argue ''This presents us with
multiple paradoxes: as the frequency of accountability goes up, the
scope of accountability gets narrower than before; as the possibility
of stable parliamentary majority recedes, it leads to greater stability
of policies that can be kept out of democratic framework; the higher
the suspense over who would eventually form the government, the lesser
it matters.'' In other words, a storm in a teacup. [The quote is taken
from an excerpt of the article published in the Hindu on 7th May 2009].
I would like to argue that whereas there are conditions under which
the Yadav-Palshikar thesis might hold, in the current conjuncture,
democratic politics has the potential of shaping policies, the potential
of making a difference.
The Yadav-Palshikar thesis: the democratic upsurge and storms
in teacups
Yadav and Palshikar argue that space created by the decline of the
Congress Party in the late 1980s and occupied for a short while by
a non-BJP, non-Congress grouping(s) has slowly been whittled away.
And this is despite the fact that the democratic upsurge – increasing
non-elite participation in voting that in part created that space
– that has characterised Indian politics in the last two decades continues
to grow, even though it has begun showing signs of slowing down.
They attribute this to two factors: first, both the BJP and the Congress
have become adept at running coalitions and therefore have taken a
fragmented electoral verdict and, at the national level, effectively
turned it into a bi-polar electoral formation, thereby squeezing out
space for an alternative political formation that had been created
with the decline of the Congress Party.
Second, and perhaps equally importantly, over the last couple of decades
there has been an increasing convergence amongst political formations
over matters of policy: economic policy, foreign policy, security
policy, issues of social justice (at least at a formal level) and
environmental policy. Therefore, around these issues, there are no
longer significant differences between political formations that are
thrashed out in and through the electoral process.
Therefore, they argue, even as the democratic upsurge in electoral
participation continues and in substantive ways democracy in India
is deepened, ideological convergence ensures that it matters less
and less as to which political formation forms the government in Delhi.
I think that Yadav and Palshikar over-emphasise ideological convergence
in policy making and therefore underplay the role that the democratic
upsurge might play in shaping the public policy agenda. Admittedly
there are areas of convergence, but these are not static or given.
They shrink as well as expand, shaped by socio-political and economic
forces, and thereby influence the potential of the democratic upsurge
to shape the public policy agenda.
The UPA coalition, its legislative agenda and ideological
space
In 2004, the Congress-led and Left-supported UPA came to power with
the clear understanding that the NDA's defeat at the hustings was
at least in part a rejection of the BJP's ‘India Shining' rhetoric.
It accepted that growth had left behind both rural and urban India's
toiling masses. It understood clearly that this inequality, particularly
in opportunities, mattered hugely both in rural and urban India. It
understood that opportunity in rural India had been seriously blighted
by the agrarian crisis. It understood that inequality in opportunity
in urban India had significantly constrained social mobility among
lower castes and that this had become politically unsustainable, in
part due to the democratic upsurge. It understood that India's polity
was in the main secular and uncomfortable with the politics of religious
identity. All of this was reflected in the UPA's Common Minimum Programme.
The UPA government introduced a slew of legislation which sought to
ameliorate some of the inequality that the process of economic growth
generated. Starting with the enactment of the National Rural Employment
Guarantee Act and the Right to Information Act in 2005, the UPA government
implemented legislation that sought to provide safety nets for those
who had been bypassed by the workings of the market. The Central Educational
Institutions (Reservation in Admission) Act 2006 expanded reservations
in admissions to institutions of higher learning to include OBCs.
In the face of sustained legal challenges, the Supreme Court of India
in April 2008 upheld the constitutional validity of both the Acts
and the 93rd amendment to the Constitution which made the Acts possible.
The Rajinder Sachar Committee, set up by the UPA government to enquire
into the social, economic and educational status of the Muslim community
in India, presented its report in 2006 and detailed the extent of
the community's marginalisation. Some of the recommendations of the
Committee have been implemented, including the setting up a National
Minorities Development and Finance Corporation.
Another important piece of legislation was the Unorganised Workers'
Social Security Bill 2008 which seeks to provide some health care,
old-age pension and disability benefits to unorganised sector workers.
Unorganised sector workers, it is worth reminding ourselves, account
for nearly 92% of the total workforce and as the reports of National
Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganised Sector (set up by the
UPA government) point out, have been completely bypassed even as the
economy's growth rates have surged. Similarly, though rather belatedly,
the implementation in 2008 of the loan waiver and debt relief programme
for farmers aimed at reducing the crushing burden of debt that has
been the major cause of pandemic-like farmer suicides that has afflicted
the rural economy for more than a decade. And finally, after a two-year
battle, the Scheduled Tribes and Traditional Forest Dwellers (Recognition
of Forest Rights) Act, 2006, that seeks to protect livelihoods and
land-rights of tribals and forest dwellers, was notified in January
2008.
There are two issues related to this legislative agenda that are germane
to our current discussion. First, that these issues were at all on
the agenda was the result of political mobilisation around these issues
by grassroots social movements, women's groups, trades unions, lower
caste groupings and left and centre-left parties. The umbrella nature
of the UPA coalition meant that this mobilisation from below could
neither be disregarded nor overlooked. Second, in implementing this
legislative agenda the UPA faced serious social and political resistance
(sometimes from within its own ranks) though not always from the same
socio-economic grouping(s) or political party (ies). Therefore very
serious political capital had to be expended to take this agenda forward.
There was therefore little ideological convergence around this legislative
agenda.
Ideological convergence: the UPA's economic policy
There was however one area in which there was ideological convergence
across the political elite (barring left parties) – economic policy.
Ever since Narasimha Rao's minority government ushered in pro-market
neoliberal economic policy reforms in 1991, there has been an agreement
across most of the political spectrum that the path to economic growth
lay through a market-led economy with minimal regulation. It is this
convergence which explains the longevity of the neoliberal economic
reform agenda and the remarkable continuity in economic policy-making
despite the fact that five governments of varying political persuasions
have come to power since the minority government of Narasimha Rao
demitted office in 1996. And despite the fact that most of the 1990s
saw a phase of ‘jobless' growth even though the economy itself grew
at a reasonably robust pace.
Therefore when the UPA government assumed power in 2004, the growth
model underpinning economic policy-making saw no change even as it
was accepted that there were serious distributional issues such as
those we have alluded to above. In retaining the same growth model,
policy makers and politicians were aided by the fact that the economy
saw a return to relatively robust employment generation, reversing
the earlier trend of ‘jobless' growth. Never mind that most of these
jobs, as the National Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganised
Sector points out, were low quality and poorly paying. Notwithstanding
that, with the economy generating both high rates of both output and
employment growth, it was felt that the only thing necessary was to
add a few safety nets (such as the NREGA and the unorganised sector
social security bill) to address politically sensitive distributional
issues. And leave the economic model well alone.
But other than through panglossian lenses, it is the neo-liberal economic
model which has been socio-economically destabilising. Financial liberalisation
and credit-fuelled consumption meant growth had an urban bias, leading
to unsustainable levels of inequality. Within service-driven urban
economies, access to quality higher education, which was effectively
filtered through caste, became a new driver of inequality. Financial
liberalisation not only swung credit flows towards urban areas but
also starved agriculture of credit. It was therefore an important
cause of the more than decade long agrarian crisis that characterised
rural India, out of which we have only now begun to emerge. Starved
of institutional credit, farmers switched to high-cost non-institutional
sources of borrowing. When farm prices collapsed globally in the 1990s,
farmers, caught in the pincer of falling prices and rising indebtedness
and with nowhere to turn, started committing suicides.
Low levels of employment growth, poor quality of employment and intense
competition for what few jobs there were meant the resurgence of sons-of-the-soil
and regional chauvinism such as we have seen in many parts of the
country, including Bengaluru and Mumbai. The lack of reasonable opportunity
outside agriculture meant, despite the agrarian crisis, a return of
land hunger – farmers were simply unwilling to sell land which they
thought of as insurance in bad times. Therefore just as rapid urbanisation
meant an increasing demand for land, acquisition of land became politically
fraught. To add to this was the great neoliberal fad of special economic
zones, where industry was to remain beyond even the most minimal labour
regulation and exempt from taxation. Here too, SEZ land acquisition
came up repeatedly against the wall of rising land hunger. And finally,
riding the commodity price boom of the late 1990s, domestic and multi-national
capital rediscovered India's mineral wealth and the Indian state(s),
ever-obliging, offered sweetheart deals. But this time around, the
long marginalised Adivasis resisted and refused to sign away their
use-rights for the pittance on offer. In the poorer parts of our country,
a combination of land hunger and Adivasi resistance saw the resurgence
of naxalite activity, widespread enough for it to be declared India's
most serious security threat.
But despite these acts of resistance and the masses of toiling Indians
who gained but little from growth, old caste and class cleavages made
alliances difficult. On the other hand, a rapidly growing economy
driven by urbanisation, a small but burgeoning middle and upper middle
class that had gained from globalisation and neoliberal policies and
an entrenched elite, ensured that the ideological convergence around
economic policy remained intact and closed off any policy-making space.
This was despite the democratic upsurge and a regular change of guard
in parliament in Delhi. It has therefore become fashionable to talk
of two Indias, almost as if they were not related – one urban, dynamic
and forward looking and the other, rural, poor and backward looking.
The two of course are. They are two sides of the same coin – to understand
the one we need to understand the other.
The global financial crisis, the unravelling of ideological
convergence and the opening of political space
So confident was the Congress Party of the continuing ideological
cohesion around economic policy and its own safety net strategy that
it pushed through the nuclear deal with the USA despite opposition
of Left parties in the coalition. And it also ensured the fact that
the UPA coalition survived the exit of Left.
Crisis did come but from a rather unexpected quarter. The collapse
of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 led to a run on investment banks
and globalised the US sub-prime crisis. And as capital flows reversed,
it exposed the Achilles heel of India's growth model. Over a period
of three months $60 billion left India, leading to a stock market
crash, a sharp decline in the value of the rupee and a liquidity and
credit squeeze in the economy. As global demand contracted on the
back of the financial crisis, India's export and manufacturing growth
saw a sharp contraction. As liquidity and credit was squeezed out
of Indian financial markets, high rates of interest choked off urban
demand growth, which has not revived even though interest rates are
at historic lows. A combination of contracting global and urban demand
saw economic growth slowdown sharply, from the heady 8-9% to around
5%. A direct consequence of this slowdown was a sharp increase in
unemployment. By some estimates as many 20 million people have been
laid off. Paradoxically, it is the revival of agricultural growth
that has saved the economy from a much sharper slowdown. As a result
of robust agricultural growth, rural incomes and demand has held up
and stabilised the economy.
Politicians (and most economists!) were of course quick to change
tack: everybody began talking about how India's financial sector (and
therefore the economy) had escaped the worst because it was much better
regulated and the RBI had much greater control over banks. Sonia Gandhi
immediately pointed out that the RBI's greater control was a direct
result of the fact that Indira Gandhi had nationalised the bulk of
the banking system in 1969! All this is not to say that as a result
of the financial crisis, economic reforms ushered in by Narasimha
Rao's government will somehow be reversed. But it is to say that the
ideological convergence around neoliberal economic policy, which had
characterised the last decade and a half, has been broken. One only
has to take a look at party manifestos for this election to see the
change – the Congress Party actually trumpeted the benefits of state
intervention and how it (the Party) always used intervention to further
economic growth. Even the BJP's manifesto worried about a purely market-led
economy! And compare this with the 2004 manifestos of both parties
where hosannas were sung to dynamic pro-market economic reforms.
Therefore an important space that was closed in the Yadav-Palshikar
hypothesis has opened up. The breaking-up of the ideological convergence
around neoliberal economic policy taken along with the democratic
upsurge that continues to animate our politics makes the 2009 Lok
Sabha elections of particular importance. It opens up the possibility
that political pressure from the democratic upsurge might finally
be able to force the crafting of a truly inclusive economic policy
that works not only for the elite and the upper middle class but also
for India's toiling masses, both urban and rural, for lower castes,
for women, for muslims, for adivasis. None of this might happen. But
the space within which it could happen has been opened up.
In this context, a few observations about the outcomes of the 2009
elections are in order. First, the Congress Party reaped the electoral
benefits of the UPA's safety net strategy and revival of rural expenditure.
Rahul Gandhi acknowledged as much when he dedicated the electoral
victory to the youth and poor of the country. Second, despite the
fact that the BJP has suffered a few reverses it still remains a politically
significant force. Third, there are today those within the Congress
Party who are sceptical of the market's ability to deliver inclusive
growth. Fourth, but equally, there are those both within and without
the Congress Party who feel that this an opportune moment to push
forward neoliberal reforms, given that the UPA does not require Left
Front support to form the next government. The battle to shape economic
policy has been joined. Finally, the Left Front's electoral debacle
could not have come at a more inopportune time, given the unravelling
of the ideological coherence around economic policy. There are of
course other ways to use that space, but a significant presence in
parliament, even outside the UPA alliance, would have helped in crafting
a more inclusive economic policy.
This is not to argue about the nature of the coalition that will form
the next government. But it is to argue, unlike Yadav and Palshikar,
that the current conjuncture does afford the possibility of democratic
electoral politics being more than a storm in a teacup.
(Mritiunjoy Mohanty teaches economics
at Indian Institute of Management Calcutta.)