The
decision of the Supreme Court to stay the implementation of the Central
Educational Institutions (Reservation in Admission) Act, 2006 is a piece
in the long and hoary tradition of the Indian Judiciary to oppose reservations
in favour of OBCs. In 1963 the Supreme Court in the famous Balaji decision
struck down OBC quotas in then Mysore state on the grounds that caste
was an insufficient basis for positive discrimination quotas and that
an overall quota of more than 50% went against the spirit of the Constitution.
The Balaji decision was used to roll back reservation in favour of OBCs
already in place in Kerala, Andhra Pradesh and Bihar.
The ruling was overturned in 1992 in the equally celebrated Indira Sawhney
case where the Supreme Court for the first time accepted that caste was
a reasonable basis for a policy of positive discrimination and therefore
implementation of the Mandal Commission recommendations were in keeping
with both the letter and spirit of the Indian Constitution. The Supreme
Court stay on the implementation of Central Educational Institutions (Reservation
in Admission) Act, 2006 was in keeping with the Balaji tradition with
a small nod at Indira Sawhney.
It is another matter that the way the Government of India argued the case
allowed the red herring of the 1931 Census as a convenient escape clause
for the learned bench. It is afterall reasonable to argue, as the Court
did, that a 2007 policy can hardly be based on information gathered on
1931, allowing it to walk down the Balaji path without running foul of
the Indira Sawhney judgment. Red herring because, as has been noted innumerable
times both in academic and non-academic discourse, there exist reasonably
reliable estimates of the OBC population put forward by the National Sample
Survey Organisation for periods as recent as 1999/2000 and 2004/5.
Perhaps equally important, in an effort to stay within the overall limit
of 50% for all quotas stipulated by the Supreme Court, the suggested quota
of 27% was significantly lower than the share of OBCs in the overall population.
This is not to argue that more accurate information such as through a
Census should not be collected. It certainly should. This is simply to
suggest that there exists sufficient information on the basis of which
to implement the Act rather than wait for more information. When that
information is available, and the sooner it is the better, implementation
can be better targeted if so necessary.
Underlying the Supreme Court’s stay is the belief that merit is being
sacrificed for political expediency. Leaving aside exceptional talent
such as the CV Ramans and Lata Mangeshkars of this world, what is called
‘merit’ is to a significant degree also influenced by an individual's
socio-economic position and/or opportunities gained by virtue of family
and social connections. Therefore, in societies like ours, characterized
as they are by deep-rooted social inequalities, an exclusive focus on
‘merit’ impedes mobility and tends to reproduce the same inequalities.
Despite upper caste protestations to the contrary it is therefore neither
democratic nor egalitarian, unless there are countervailing tendencies.
I have argued elsewhere (Social Inequality, Labour Market Dynamics and
Reservation, EPW, 2nd September 2006) that changing labour market dynamics
and privileged access to high quality tertiary education has meant upper
caste hindus (UCH) in the last decade or so have dominated access to the
best jobs in the urban economy. As a result, in the urban economy, SCs,
STs and OBCs are similarly situated and at a great distance from UCH.
More than anything else, it is this changing dynamics of the labour market
that necessitates widening the ambit of reservations in institutions of
higher learning to include OBCs. In obstructing this process the Supreme
Court runs the risk of being perceived as being both unfair and partisan.
But then UCH elite have long used their domination of the judiciary and
the bureaucracy as mechanisms of passive resistance in their continuing
battle to retain control over socio-economic levers of power. Consider
two examples of radical public policy initiatives, the successful implementation
of which might have altered the trajectory of India’s socio-economic growth:
the implementation of land reform and the SC/ST quota both of which were
a part of the socio-economic compact that led to the birth of the Indian
republic in 1950. Whereas zamindari was successfully abolished, the distribution
of land declared surplus (beyond legally permissible holdings) was effectively
stymied as land transfer got caught up a maze of litigation, bureaucratic
obfuscation and lack of political will.
Similarly as a response to Ambedkar’s mobilization and Gandhi’s insistence,
the UCH elite acceded to constitutionally guaranteed quotas for SCs and
STs. However by ensuring that these quotas did not get filled, particularly
in the higher echelons of the bureaucracy, judiciary and the public sector
(including colleges and universities), the UCH elite ensured that any
transformative potential was snuffed out. And rather than a debate why
quotas remain unfilled, UCH elites, under the garb of equality, removed
the ‘creamy layer’ from within the purview of the quota, effectively snuffing
out the possibility of the formation of a countervailing elite.
OBC quotas have been resisted much more strenuously, in part because UCH
elites have always seen OBCs, as compared with the SCs and STs, as being
a much more serious threat to the continued control over the socio-economic
levers of power. UCH elites have been successful in using passive resistance
as a blocking strategy because there was insufficient grass-roots political
mobilization around these issues. It can hardly be a coincidence that
the states where land reforms (e.g., Kerala and West Bengal) or SC/ST/OBC
quotas (e.g., Tamil Nadu) have been successfully implemented are states
where there has been political mobilization around these issues.
But successful blocking strategies and elite resistance have also resulted
in growing lower caste political mobilization. One of the outcomes of
UCH elite resistance to Mandal was the re-drawing of the political map
of India with a politically assertive lower caste mobilization. Therefore
if, on the one hand, changing labour market dynamics and continued UCH
domination of the most dynamic segments of the urban economy as a result
of privileged access to institutions of higher learning necessitate an
expansion of reservations in favour of OBCs, then on the other, UCH elite
blocking strategies become politically counter-productive and socially
expensive, as institutional and social energy is spent in coming up with
effective strategies of exclusion, rather than devising strategies of
inclusion and building a consensus around which to take this old society
forward.
* The author teaches economics
at IIM Calcutta
|