To
the superstitious, recent developments in global financial markets were
possible reminders that the Ides of March had arrived. To the more rational,
they proved once again that finance capital, which pillories the state
when it steps into the economic arena, finally uses it as a means of accumulation
and leans on it in times of crisis.
On March 14, Bear Stearns, the fifth largest investment bank in the United
States with an 85-year history, was put on life support with what appears
to be an unlimited loan facility for 28 days delivered through Wall Street
Bank J.P. Morgan Chase. The need for life support came when it is became
clear that, faced with a liquidity crunch, Bear Stearns would have to
unwind its assets by selling them at prices that would imply huge losses.
This would have had spin off effects on other financial firms since the
investment bank had multiple points of interaction with the rest of the
financial community. Besides being a counterpart to a range of transactions
that would turn questionable, its efforts to liquidate its assets would
affect other investors holding the same or related securities and derivatives
through a price decline. Fearing that the ripple effects would lead to
a systemic collapse, the Fed, in collaboration with JP Morgan, sought
to prop up the investment bank. The Financial Times quotes an unnamed
official who reportedly declared that Bear Stearns was too "interconnected"
to be allowed to fail at a time when financial markets are extremely fragile.
According to insiders, in addition to the loans extended to Bear Stearns,
the Fed has agreed to fund up to $30 billion of its less liquid assets,
so as to prevent a distress sale of mortgage-backed securities.
The Fed's support was clearly driven by two objectives. The first was
to keep Bear Stearns afloat so that its liquidation would not trigger
a financial collapse. The second was to restore the firm to a condition
where it could find an appropriate suitor willing to take it over. In
fact, speculation was rife that with JP Morgan being chosen as the conduit
to deliver funds to Bear Stearns, it would be in a privileged position
to take over the firm at an appropriate time.
That time arrived in two days. Clearly JP Morgan was convinced that the
support being offered was good enough to help revive the enterprise from
its pathetic position. And a takeover when the firm is going through a
crisis and shareholders are looking to exit promises a better bargain
than when its health has been restored. Thus, in a deal negotiated over
a weekend and clinched on a Sunday, JP Morgan agreed to buy Bear Stearns
for $236 million in shares, or at a price of $2 a share. The deal took
Wall Street and the financial community by surprise, not just because
of the speed with which it was executed. Rather, what was stunning was
the price - a 93 per cent discount on the price at which it was being
quoted at closing on the immediately preceding Friday and way below the
$169 at which the shares were being traded just over a year ago. Further,
the deal gave JP Morgan ownership of Bear's headquarters in Manhattan's
Madison Avenue—a piece of real estate valued at $1.2 billion. The Fed's
move had provided the basis for a deal that would put prices quoted in
bargain basements to shame.
The import of the Fed's decision to support Bear Stearns needs noting.
The philosophy that rules financial markets and financial policy today
is that bail-outs by the government of institutions that are weakened
by wrong financial decisions are inimical to the proper functioning of
markets in the long run. Such bail-outs are expected to result in moral
hazard problems, or the tendency for agents protected against risk to
behave recklessly, that destroy markets. Moreover, they are seen as legitimising
interventionism, which then that leads to distortions and financial repression
that increases market inefficiency. Indeed, the very financial liberalisation
that created the problems epitomised by the sub-prime crisis was predicated
on a critique of the efficacy and correctness of intervention by the state.
The "problem" that liberalisation was directed to "solve"
could not itself become the solution to the problems that liberalisation
creates.
Further, even those who see in the Federal Reserve and similar institutions
a lender of last resort which must step in when liquidity dries up and
threatens financial failure, see this role as relevant only to the commercial
banking sector, which takes deposits insured by the deposit insurance
corporation. Even that was a responsibility that was linked to rights
to regulate the commercial banking system. The responsibility of ensuring
liquidity to unregulated or lightly regulated merchant banks and other
such segments of the financial system does not conventionally rest with
the central bank. In the circumstances, the Federal Reserve had to adopt
the unusual route of routing its support through J P Morgan—a commercial
bank—in a back to back transaction that promises the bank the liquidity
needed to service demands from Bear Stearns. According to a statement
from JP Morgan: "Through its discount window, the Fed will provide
non-recourse, back-to-back financing to JPMorgan Chase. Accordingly, JPMorgan
Chase does not believe this transaction exposes its shareholders to any
material risk."
According to one report, the Fed claims that it was acting under section
13.3 of the Federal Reserve Act, which gives it authority to lend to any
individual, partnership or corporation "in unusual and exigent circumstances".
But that authority has not been invoked since the 1960s and loans under
that regime were actually disbursed only during the Depression in the
1930s.
As opposed to liquidity problems that could afflict a conventional bank,
Bear Stearns' predicament was the result of wrong decisions encouraged
by a liberal or lightly regulated and ostensibly "innovative"
financial framework. Though successful in the past, it was a highly leveraged
institution holding assets valued at $395.4 billion in November 2007 on
an equity base of just $11.8 billion. Bear was also heavily exposed to
the "lucrative" sub-prime loan market that has been on the decline
since the middle of last year. Eight months earlier the bank had declared
that investments in one of its hedge funds set up to invest in mortgage
backed securities had lost all its value and those in a second such fund
were valued at nine cents for every dollar of original investment. Since
then, the bank's exposure to the mortgage market has been shown to be
substantial. The resulting losses were huge and creditors were unwilling
to keep providing the finance to back investments that were dwindling
in value. The bank broke when hedge fund Carlyle Capital Corporation,
to which it was heavily exposed, went bankrupt. So would Bear Stearns
have, if the Fed had not stepped in with its life support arrangements.
But this use of the state to rescue a mismanaged financial enterprise
(or system) does not begin or end with Bear Stearns. The problems the
latter faced eight months back were a strong indicator of a sub-prime-led
crisis that had burgeoned because of financial greed, poor and faulty
financial practices and weak regulation. What soon became clear was that
the potential for crisis in the mortgage market was huge, and the direct
and indirect exposure of leading financial firms to that market was widespread
both in terms of institutions and geography. The entangled financial system
that liberalisation, securitisation and structured products of various
kinds had generated had put a wide variety of institutions in the net.
Since the base problem was massive the consequences could be devastating.
The response was a decision across the world, but especially in the US
and the UK, for the state to step in, stall a crisis and restore normalcy
at the expense of the tax payer if necessary. This whole strategy is based
on the idea that if financial institutions have enough liquidity at relatively
low costs to meet their needs and do not have to unwind their assets at
declining prices the problem would in time go away. The net result is
huge cuts in interest rates and efforts to beef up liquidity in the system.
What the Bear Stearns experience indicates is that the Fed is willing
to reach that liquidity ‘almost' directly to unregulated institutions
other than commercial banks.
The problem these institutions faced was that the short term financing
they obtained from the market was in exchange for the assets or securities
they held, temporarily sold only to be repurchased later. But with the
value of these securities declining, banks providing such loans were asking
for larger discounts or more collateral or in fact were unwilling to lend
against certain kinds of securities. Just days before the near-collapse
of Bear Stearns the Fed had announced a facility under which it would
lend primary dealers in the bond market $200billion in Treasury securities
for a month at a time and accept ordinary triple-A rated mortgage-backed
securities as collateral in return. That is, the Fed was swapping good
paper for paper which everybody believes was wrongly rate and is as good
as junk. The dealers themselves could then use the Treasury securities
to borrow from the market. Unfortunately for Bear Stearns, this rescue
attempt came too late for it to exercise the option.
But it is still unclear that this effort by the Fed to break all rules
and take on junk created by a malfunctioning financial system would solve
the problem. It leaves the base problem of a mortgage crisis reflected
in rising defaults unresolved. That makes the assets sitting in the books
of many financial institutions worthless. The issue is not just one of
illiquidity but of insolvency.
But there is reason to believe that if easy and cheap liquidity, which
allows financial firms to access cheap short term funds to finance higher
return medium or long term investments, does not help neutralise other
losses, the state would step in to restructure the capital of these institutions
at taxpayers' expense. This was what was done during the savings and loan
crisis in the US. And this seems to be what was done in the case of Northern
Rock in the UK.
Northern Rock, the fifth largest mortgage lender in the UK was also trapped
in rising mortgage defaults, and had to be rescued by the Bank of England
with access to liquidity against collateral in the form of mortgages or
mortgage backed securities. Sensing failure, depositors queued up to withdraw
their savings necessitating rapid increases in lending to the institution.
When it was clear that it was insolvency that threatened Northern Rock,
the Bank of England and the Chancellor tried to find a suitor who would
buy into the bank. For that purpose it declared that it was willing to
convert the £25 billion ($49 billion) Bank of England debt it had
incurred into bonds that would be backed by a government guarantee so
that they could be sold to investors. The issue was how long the government
would have to guarantee the bonds, what would be the fee that would be
paid to the government as guarantor and what would be the equity stake
the government would get to make a profit from equity appreciation when
viability is restored. Three private bidders who expressed an interest
in the deal were looking for a major sop from the government that would
guarantee them huge profits. When that was not forthcoming, all but one
(Richard Branson's Virgin Group) withdrew, and the last was holding out
for a bargain. In the end the government had to nationalise the bank rather
than subsidise the private player to earn the profit that the government
helps generate.
Nationalisation of course implies that the institution is being restructured
with taxpayer funds that would be recouped, if at all, only in the medium
term. How much private shareholders, include major funds, should be compensated
for what is a worthless enterprise without government guarantees is being
debated. Finance capital seeks every means possible to accumulate at the
expense of the state, even in the midst of a crisis it has created. Meanwhile,
arguments from Northern Rock's private competitors that government support
makes the playing field unequal, are being used to limit the lender's
activities. This could mean that the tax payers' money would not be recouped.
Martin Wolf, the conservative columnist for the Financial Times (February
17, 2008) has to his credit supported nationalization and opposed compensating
shareholders. But he has a rather intriguing suggestion as to where the
government should go from here: "The bank should be nationalised
and then closed for new mortgage business. That is the only way to ensure
that its continued existence does not distort the mortgage market as a
whole. It would be the least bad end to this depressing saga." But
what about recouping the financing provided by the government to cover
loans from the central bank? The government must wait, he says. Even if
the loan book is run down, "When the financial markets recover, it
should be possible to sell the residual loan book. Provided its quality
is as good as the auditors and the Financial Services Authority have suggested,
the government should get back all the money it has lent the bank."
In sum: let the state we pillory carry and pass the burden of preventing
a financial collapse to the tax payer for the present, and hope the markets
would compensate it for its good work in due time.
|