Last
week I had occasion to drive to a village located some distance outside
Delhi. At least, I thought I would be driving to a village outside Delhi,
through rural roads traversing many villages. And I looked forward to
experiencing on the journey some of the sense of openness that comes to
city dwellers when they visit rural spaces. I had anticipatory visions
of acres of farmland under the rabi wheat crop, or glorious yellow fields
of mustard, all around me as I travelled.
Instead,
I drove for several hours along narrow paved roads bordered on both sides
by enormous walls. It was impossible to see any "fields", because
the entire area of farmland all around had been enclosed into properties
of the (mostly urban-based) rich: huge palatial farm houses surrounded
by their manicured gardens and lawns, and some vegetable patches that
are the casual concession to agriculture in these new manifestations of
rurality.
The
walls along the road changed in character every so often, as the ownership
of the properties apparently changed. But they had some characteristics
in common: they were all sufficiently high as to inhibit any curious passer-by
from observing anything behind them, and forbiddingly preventive of any
attempt at "unlawful" entry through the extensive use of barbed
wire and splintered glass on top. These private walls were also typically
quite wide and imposing, so that the narrow "village" road in
between was not only hemmed in and sandwiched between them, but also seemed
like nothing more than a rather forlorn passageway from these elite residences
to the nearby urban centres.
The
"villages", or what remained of them, had become little clusters
of habitations and small shops along the road, hemmed in to such an extent
that the only openness came from the sky above. Even trees had been removed
from most of the road, to allow for the encroaching and demarcating private
walls to establish their defining presence.
The
shops and petty commercial establishments too reflected the material change
that has overtaken this countryside, dominated by real estate agents that
specialised in farm houses, hardware shops for construction activity,
the occasional auto repair shops that advertised their ability to deal
with SUVs, and the new staple of such environments: the private security
agencies for the protection of the new wealthy residents. Even the inevitable
small kirana shops were interspersed with the outlets of large corporate
retailers and the occasional designer boutique for furniture and artefacts.
It
is hard to figure out when exactly this happened or how long the transformation
took, but it appears that the process is now almost complete. A large
part of the rural area around Delhi and its satellite cities has been
converted into the private playgrounds of the rich, the site for their
occasional rest, recreation and celebration, and is only nominally farmland
any more. It is not held by small peasants, or even by those who get the
larger part of their income from farming, but by those who see this as
one more piece of attractive real estate in a portfolio of land holding.
In
the process, the attributes of the villages of these formerly completely
rural areas are changing fast, not only in terms of ownership and cultivation
patterns, but also in terms of the material means of support of the local
population and their lifestyles. The question of course arises as to what
happens to the villagers themselves, a significant proportion of whom
must have lost their lands to these new urban entrants, and others who
would have formerly worked either as rural labour or in providing the
farming community with various local crafts and services.
It
is likely that this process is not something that is confined to Delhi
– reports from other major metros suggest that similar things are happening
in the rural areas around Mumbai, Bangalore, Hyderabad and Chennai as
well, to take only a few examples. The irony is that all this is of course
still classified as land under agricultural use, with all the attendant
economic and legal implications.
There
has been much discussion, debate and outcry about land use conversion
in India recently. There is no question that the transformation of land
from agricultural to industrial or other non-agricultural use, however
desirable the ultimate goal may or may not be, is a process that is painful,
fraught with conflict and redolent of class struggle. This is now widely
recognised, even by the central and state governments, so that issues
of compensation and rehabilitation have become high priorities on the
policy agenda.
However,
there is little discussion – or even awareness - about cases where land
is "voluntarily" sold by farmers to bigger players, and officially
still remains as agricultural land. Yet, if the proliferation of private
enclosures in the rural areas around Delhi to create garden homes for
the rich is any indication, this is a silent but extensive tendency that
is dramatically affecting both land use patterns and class relations in
the rural peripheries of many of our cities.
Unlike
some other land use conversion involving industrial use, this process
does not even create any new jobs, and so is probably an even larger net
destroyer of local employment. So it is probably time for this process
to be taken note of and addressed, in terms of considering whether such
new development really deserves to be still treated as farmland, and what
is to be done about the conditions of those who have been displaced by
it.
This
is doubly important because this process is closely analogous to the real
estate development that is currently the chief instrument of land use
conversion in the rural hinterland of urban areas across the country.
The boom in real estate and property has spawned more than an explosion
of high-rise construction in city centres. It has generated very rapid
and aggressive urban extension, with new commercial, residential and entertainment-oriented
construction coming up in what were previously agricultural areas, and
transforming them also into effectively urban locations.
In
the National Capital Region, for instance, that is the area including
Delhi and the satellite cities of Noida, Faridabad, Ghaziabad and Gurgaon,
it has been estimated that land is being purchased from farmers, developed
and thereby diverted from agriculture at the rate of around 10,000 hectares
per year. This reflects the operation of "market forces" in
that there is no involvement of the state in either regulating prices
or ensuring fair compensation and rehabilitation to all those who earlier
earned a livelihood from such land.
The trouble with such market-determined transfer is that the farmers who
were the original holders of the land rarely get anything close to the
real value of the land because they are typically dealing with larger,
more corporate and well-informed buyers who can more correctly anticipate
the potential urban development. The cash amounts involved may seem large
to the farmers at first, but are often frittered away in consumption and
do not enable the households concerned to sustain themselves over time.
Most
of all, such a market process denies any possibility of compensation and
rehabilitation to other stakeholders of that previous land holding pattern,
such as tenants and agricultural workers. That is why it is so important
for the state to be involved in mediating such transactions and ensuring
that adequate compensation is provided in a sustainable manner. Of course
such involvement of the state must itself be democratically accountable
and directed towards serving the interests of the displaced, rather than
of the displacers.
However, the very fact that such real estate development covers not just
corporate and commercial expansion but also residential accommodation,
including possibly apartment complexes and flats for the middle classes
and the less well-off groups, makes the political stakes more complex.
The group of beneficiaries of this process of land transfer then contains
many who would protest the more open land grab by large corporates that
is associated with the development of SEZs.
But that is all the more reason why such land transfer should not go unnoticed
and why such silent displacement – with possibly socially damaging effects
– should not be allowed to proceed in so unregulated a manner.
|