The
defeat of the NDA in the last elections was a source of consternation
in international financial circles. The Wall Street Journal even asked
editorially: "Why should developing countries like India have such
frequent elections?" And it went on to add that if a country like
India does have elections, then surely the outcome can not be left entirely
to the Indian people; "foreign investors" too must have a say
since they have a "stake" in the Indian economy. Similar views
were aired in public and private in Washington DC among the Fund-Bank
staff and among the financial bureaucracy and the "financial class"
within India. Nerves were soothed only when it became clear that policy-making,
at least in economic matters, would be entrusted to three persons who
had been closely associated with the induction of "neo-liberal"
policies, namely Dr.Manmohan Singh, Mr.Chidambaram and Mr.Ahluwalia. Even
so, Mr.Chidambaram had to miss the first session of Parliament for some
days during which he made a trip to Mumbai to reassure the leading lights
of the stock-market regarding the new government"s adherence to the
"liberalization" agenda.
It is important to understand the reasons behind the financial circles"
consternation. On several issues ranging from Employment Guarantee to
disinvestment in PSUs, to social sector expenditure, the Congress Party"s
Manifesto, many of whose proposals subsequently found their way into the
National Common Minimum Programme, had a thrust very different from that
of the "liberalization" agenda. Perceiving the popular mood,
it envisaged a more active role for the State in promoting employment
and welfare. And this is anathema for international finance capital which
is interested not in a "retreat of the State", as is often claimed,
but in a transformation of the State into an instrument for promoting
its own exclusive interests.
The reason for its opposition to State activism in matters of employment
and relief for the people however lies not just in its preference for
a different, and from its point of view "better", State. It
opposes such "State activism" for two other basic reasons. First,
such activism destroys its own social legitimacy. Even capitalists engaged
in production, who stand to gain, by way of larger profits, from the boost
to economic activity that comes from larger State investment, invariably
oppose the existence of a public sector (they want public ownership of
any profitable unit to be only a transient phenomenon), because it undermines
their legitimacy: if it becomes clear that the State too can run enterprises,
then a class of capitalists, whose necessity is supposed to lie specifically
in their exclusive ability to perform this task, becomes palpably superfluous.
This fear is even greater for finance capital, which essentially represents
rentier interests, with very little involvement in production, and which
therefore sustains, in Lenin"s words, a class of "coupon-clipping"
"parasites". The absurd myth that the state of the stock-market
determines the pace of accumulation and hence the vigour of a capitalist
economy, and the conclusion that everything must be done to keep the stock-market
buoyant even to achieve social goals, which finance capital so self-servingly
promotes through its various mouthpieces including the media, will cease
to be sustainable if the State steps in for providing employment and relief.
Finance capital therefore opposes such State activism at all costs.
Secondly, the rolling back of dirigisme has the added advantage, from
the point of view of finance capital, that it unleashes a process of "primitive
accumulation" of capital through the privatization "for a song"
of public enterprises. On the other hand if the State were to be more
active in providing employment and relief to the people, then not only
would this bonanza be denied, but there might even be heavier taxation
of capitalists.
Modus
Operandi of Deflation: FRBM Act
The
modus operandi of imposing expenditure cuts on the government is through
legislation such as the Fiscal Responsibility and Budgetary Management
Act, which had been passed under the NDA government, and which the UPA
government promptly owned upon assuming office, even though the Act constitutes
an extraordinarily irrational piece of legislation. The Act provides for
a reduction, in a manner stipulated by itself, in the magnitude of the
fiscal deficit to a ceiling of 3 percent of GDP. When there is no legislation
stipulating the minimum tax-GDP ratio, when there is no legislation stipulating
the minimum ratio of social sector expenditure to GDP, when there is no
legislation stipulating the minimum expenditure on anti-poverty programmes
to GDP, why there should be a law that stipulates the maximum ratio of
fiscal deficit to GDP is baffling to start with, when there is absolutely
no theoretical reason to believe that a fiscal deficit is necessarily
harmful. Matters become even more bizarre when it is recalled that this
ratio is supposed to hold good under all circumstances, whether there
is a recession or not, whether there is a collapse of employment or not,
whether there is massive poverty or not. And the bizarreness only increases
when it is recalled that a rise in the fiscal deficit does not necessarily
mean a rise in the government"s net borrowing.
Consider a simple example. Suppose the government borrows from the banking
system Rs.100 to spend on an employment generation programme. Let us also
assume for simplicity that the only commodity for which demand is generated
through the expenditure on such a programme is foodgrains. If there are
plenty of foodgrain stocks in the economy rotting in the godowns even
as people go hungry owing to lack of purchasing power, then it would be
plain stupid, indeed criminal, on the part of the government, not to undertake
this expenditure because the fiscal deficit would increase thereby. But
the stupidity in such a case is even greater than appears at first sight.
The Rs.100 spent on the programme would accrue back to the FCI which holds
the foodgrain stocks, which itself is a government-owned entity. The FCI
may use the money to repay its bank loans by Rs.100. In this case what
the government"s right hand (i.e. the budget) has borrowed from banks
is paid by its left hand (the FCI), with no increase in the government"s
net indebtedness to banks. Indeed if FCI transactions figured as part
of the budget, as they used to do till the early seventies, then the fiscal
deficit in the budget itself would have shown no increase. But the mere
convention of not showing FCI transactions in the budget would mean that
government expenditure on such an employment programme through borrowing
from the banks would be disallowed under the FRBM Act. This Act therefore
prevents the government from increasing demand in the economy, including
demand in the public sector even when this sector is saddled with unutilized
capacity and unemployment. It ensures both an eschewing of State activism
for undertaking investment, and providing employment and relief (and hence
an unrolling of red carpet for MNCs to undertake investment in lieu of
the State, even through offers of guaranteed rates of return in foreign
exchange), and the perpetuation of "sickness" in the public
sector units which then is used as an excuse to "privatize"
them for a song. Professor Joan Robinson, one of the outstanding progressive
economists of the twentieth century, called this self-serving argument
of finance capital against fiscal deficits the "humbug of finance".
The UPA is officially as committed to this "humbug" as the NDA
was, though under the force of the circumstances it has both postponed
the target date for reaching the ceilings specified under the FRBM Act,
and used several subterfuges to get around its stringency, as we shall
see later in the context of the 2005-06 budget.
While the considerations underlying finance capital"s promotion of
"liberalization" and the resulting transformation in the nature
of the State are thus quite obvious, its being "international"
gives the efforts of finance capital a spontaneous effectiveness. Any
State that refuses to transform itself into a servitor of financial interests
would find itself faced with a flight of finance from its economy, unless
it imposes controls on the free movements of capital into and out of its
shores, i.e. unless it reverses the "liberalization agenda"
and sets up an alternative dialectic to that of "liberalization".
It follows that the so-called "liberalization with a human face"
is a contradiction in terms. If a "human face" is to be put
on the development process, through the provision of employment and relief
by the State, then willy-nilly the process of "liberalization"
has to be reversed; on the other hand if the process of "liberalization"
is persisted with, then one can forget about the "human face".
International finance capital is instinctively aware of this. And that
is why when the UPA government came to power, it was stunned for a while,
especially since the dependence of the government on Left support meant
that it could not make a simple about turn with impunity on the NCMP.
There is in short a fundamental opposition between the interests of the
people and the interests of international finance capital and the domestic
big bourgeois and financial class aligned to it. The entire period since
the UPA came to power has been a period of intense struggle arising from
this opposition. While appeasing financial interests and soothing the
nerves of international financial capital, the government has not been
able to push ahead with the "liberalization" agenda to the extent
it would have liked; it has faced stiff opposition at every step from
the Left on whose support it depends for its survival. At the same time
it has reneged on every one of the major promises made in the NCMP, with
the Left mounting intense pressure against such reneging. Some of the
critical areas of such struggle are highlighted below.
The
Employment Guarantee Scheme
Perhaps
the most striking provision of the NCMP was the scheme for giving 100
days of assured employment to one member in every rural household. This
itself was a comedown from the Congress Party"s election promise
of giving 100 days of assured employment to one member from each household,
both urban and rural. The idea of assuring employment to only one member
per rural household was obviously discriminatory against women; and in
any case the scheme promised only paltry relief, since only 100 days of
assured employment per household did not amount to much. Even so, the
scheme was important in the context of the sharp deterioration in the
living conditions, including per capita food absorption, of the rural
poor, which had come about through the drastic curtailment in rural purchasing
power arising inter alia from the cutback in rural development expenditure
of the government. This cutback in turn was a consequence of the reduced
tax revenue and the compressed fiscal deficit that neo-liberal policies
had engendered.
From the very beginning however the scheme aroused fierce opposition,
first in the name of a resource constraint, and subsequently, when even
the Planning Commission found that the total expenditure for running such
a scheme would be no more than Rs.25000 crores annually at present, which
is no more than 1 percent of the GDP, in the name of administrative difficulties.
When even this failed to carry conviction, the opposition to the scheme
took up the familiar refrain: "why waste money providing what in
effect would be a dole when that money could be better used for increasing
the growth rate and providing more meaningful productive employment through
that route?" It was conveniently forgotten that if high growth could
provide more productive employment in adequate quantities, then the very
fact of rural distress and the very need for an employment guarantee scheme
would not have arisen in the first place.
The real objection to the EGS was the fact that it went against entire
thrust of neo-liberalism, promoted by international finance capital, of
rolling back State activism in matters of employment and relief for the
people. And this objection was reflected in the Draft Bill that was presented
to the Parliament. The Draft replicates the basic flaw inherent in the
original NCMP provision itself, namely, that by taking the household as
the unit it ignores the claims of all individual adults for employment
guarantee, and thereby also implicitly discriminates against women. In
addition however the Draft reneges on the NCMP itself in at least three
crucial ways: first, it does not provide for the extension of the scheme
to cover the entire country within a specified period of time; secondly,
even in areas where it is to be introduced the Draft allows the government
to withdraw the scheme at will; and thirdly, the scheme according to the
Draft is supposed to be targeted towards "poor households",
which is a clear violation of the NCMP promise of a universal employment
guarantee that is so essential, both because of the gross underestimation
of poverty and the woefully inadequate identification of the "poor",
and because universality confers a right and is therefore a means of empowerment
of the working masses. In addition, the Draft does not ensure employment
at the statutory minimum wage, and, by insisting on a narrow definition
of "productive work", effectively ensures that most people covered
under it would be entitled at best to some unemployment insurance which
would be no more than a pittance. In short, instead of the significant
action on the employment front, notwithstanding all limitations, that
was envisaged in the NCMP, what we have is a damp squib.
The Draft is before the Standing Committee, and the coming days will see
an intense struggle between the democratic and progressive forces on the
one hand pressing for a worthwhile EGS, and a recalcitrant government
on the other resisting this pressure. Afraid to alienate finance capital,
the government may attempt to split the progressive forces by demanding
a price for a larger EGS in the form of cutting some other relief expenditure;
and, if pushed, it may even consider associating the World Bank and other
such organizations in the financing of it. Since these organizations typically
demand their "pound of flesh" for such financing and then quietly
drop the scheme after having obtained this "pound of flesh",
associating them would mean not a departure from the "liberalization"
agenda but, on the contrary, an active promotion of it under the false
pretense of introducing a "human face".
The Financial Sector
A second area of struggle has been the financial sector. A precondition
for any relief to the people, it follows from the foregoing, is control
over financial flows, which obviates the need for pursuing policies catering
to the caprices of finance. The Left has been asking for such controls
for a long time. But matters have come to such a pass, with foreign exchange
reserves crossing $140 billion, and as much as $10 billion being added
in the mere space of four weeks ending March 11, that even the Governor
of the Reserve Bank of India asked for some checks on financial inflows,
which, as he had expressed it once earlier, were using India "as
a parking place for dollars". Within minutes of his having asked
for such checks, he was asked by the Finance Minister to eat his words,
which he duly did at a hurriedly-convened Press Conference rather late
at night. In short, the government is adamant on maintaining liberal financial
flows into and out of the country, and this is extracting a heavy price
from the economy, apart from precluding any relief for the people owing
to the constant need to retain speculators" "confidence".
This heavy price is because of the fact that while the country hardly
gets any return on these reserves (the average rate of return is supposed
to be around 1.5 percent), those whose inflows have contributed to these
reserves are getting huge returns (inclusive of capital gains), well over
20 percent, on the funds they have brought in. Since holding reserves
is analogous to lending abroad (since it entails holding "IOU"s
of foreign governments and banks) the country in effect is borrowing dear
to lend cheap which is both silly as well as ominous for the future. On
the other hand, not holding these reserves would make the rupee appreciate
in the face of such inflows, which would mean a de-industrialization of
the economy paid for by short-term borrowing. If for instance $100 flow
in, then, if reserves are not held, the rupee would appreciate until a
current account deficit of $100 has been created through an increase in
imports at the expense of domestic output; this would mean a shrinking
of domestic activity and unemployment. The country"s debt in other
words would have increased in order to finance its own ruin through de-industrialization,
or it would have experienced what one can call a "debt-financed de-industrialization".
If this is to be avoided, as well as the silly and ominous piling up of
reserves, then the only way is to control financial inflows, which are
being used entirely for speculative purposes. The RBI governor, by no
means a radical or Leftist, had suggested just this. The government obviously
however has no intention of getting off this perilous course.
Indeed on the contrary it is attempting two further steps which are exceedingly
dangerous: the first is to move ahead towards capital account convertibility,
and the second is to push financial liberalization even further so that
the economy gets even more closely enmeshed in the vortex of globalized
finance. A whole series of measures, such as merging public sector banks;
enlarging the equity base of the public sector banks, apparently for satisfying
the "Basle norms", through attracting private holders; allowing
foreign banks to take over private sector banks; the shift away from development
banking; the permission given to specialized development finance institutions
(IDBI being the latest example) to start banking operations; the permission
given to banks to operate on stock exchanges and commodity exchanges;
the tolerance shown to banks which flout priority sector lending norms;
and indeed the attempt to cover up banks" transgressions in this
regard by expanding the definition of "priority sector"; are
but a few illustrations of the government"s determination to detach
the financial sector in India from its obligation to serve the needs of
the productive national economy, and to make it instead an integral part
of the world of international finance.
The era of planning and of the pursuit of a strategy of relatively autonomous
capitalist development had seen a transformation of the financial sector
in India from serving the needs of a colonial economy and of a few monopoly
houses that had developed in the interstices of the colonial economy (especially
after the grant of "discriminating protection" in the twenties
and thirties) to facilitating accelerated and a broader-based capitalist
development, including in agriculture through the "Green Revolution"
(after bank nationalization). This transformation, starting with the nationalization
of the Imperial Bank of India and the setting up of specialized financial
institutions like IDBI, IFCI, ICICI, and SFCs, and ending with the nationalization
of large private sector banks, had created the basis for building up the
productive base of the economy in all its diversity.
What we are seeing now is yet another transformation. The case for the
merger of public sector banks in terms of economies of scale is entirely
unfounded. And as for the argument that such merger is necessary to make
Indian banks withstand foreign competition in the new environment, it
is amusing that this argument is being advanced not by the banks themselves
groaning under the impact of some presumed un-competitiveness but by Mr.Chidambaram
and Finance Ministry bureaucrats, who, day in and day out, preach the
virtues of State non-intervention! The real idea behind this merger and
allowing foreign banks to take over private Indian banks (that is so at
present, but later no doubt they would be allowed to take over public
sector banks as well) is to have a limited number of large players, led
by foreign banks, in the banking sphere who would then go global, engage
in speculative and high profit activities, detach themselves entirely
from the "messy" business of lending to a host of peasants and
petty producers, and get monopoly control (especially the foreign banks)
over the debt of the government (or what is called "sovereign debt")
which is a highly prized plum even today as it was in Lenin"s time.
The result would not only be the end of the era of banks serving the needs
of production, but the creation of an ambience where financial crises
of the East Asian kind would occur, resulting in a stagnation of the economy
and a de-nationalization of its assets.
The Bank Employees are already struggling hard to prevent such a denouement.
The Left is aware of the dangers of the course being advocated by the
Finance Ministry. The coming months would see intense struggles over these
measures.
The Alibi of the Need for FDI
The case for financial liberalization as a total package is ultimately
argued on the grounds of the presumed need for FDI. Prime Minister Manmohan
Singh pleaded before a bunch of financiers in New York that unless India
got $150 billion FDI over a 15 year period to improve her infrastructure,
her economic prospects were bleak. This cringing before metropolitan finance,
though it started with the NDA and hence predates the UPA, certainly marks
a enormous departure from the earlier days, when Prashanta Chandra Mahalanobis
had gone lecturing all over America about how India was embarking on a
massive industrialization effort on her own and with her own resources.
The favourite ploy of our current leaders of course is to cite the example
of China which these days gets around $50 billion FDI each year compared
to $3-4 billion of India: the suggestion is made that without such heavy
investment China could not achieve her extraordinary growth rates, and
that if India wanted such high growth rates then she too would have to
woo FDI assiduously.
This argument is wrong on several counts. First, the large influx of FDI
is hardly necessary at present for China"s remarkable growth performance.
China, as is well-known, has massive and growing foreign exchange reserves
which are built up out of her own earnings in the form of current account
surpluses, and not through speculative financial inflows as in the case
of India. She is in other words maintaining an excess of savings over
non-FDI-financed investment. Her need for investible resources from outside
therefore is correspondingly less. FDI in her case could be a useful means
of bringing in technology or of marketing her products, but for these
purposes technical collaboration or marketing agreements could do as well.
Her reasons for large FDI inflows at present therefore remain obscure.
At any rate, inflows on this scale are certainly unnecessary for the maintenance
of her growth rate. Secondly, FDI typically flows into those economies
which already have high domestic savings rates anyway. It does not constitute
a means of compensating for low domestic savings. Since India has a savings
rate much lower than in the East and South East Asian countries, and since
this rate has not gone up at all during the period of "liberalization",
to pin hopes on FDI to provide a way out of this situation is a chimera.
Thirdly, in the case of India, as suggested earlier, there is plenty of
unutilized capacity, within the public sector itself, which can be used
with impunity for boosting public investment through an enlarged fiscal
deficit, without even having to raise tax revenue.
In short, FDI is both unnecessary for boosting India"s growth rate
and unlikely to come in any significant quantities, despite all the blandishments
being offered. But since these blandishments include financial liberalization,
which necessarily engenders deflation and cut backs in public investment,
that in turn have a discouraging effect on private investment, all this
wooing of FDI in the name of stepping up the investment ratio is paradoxically
having the opposite effect of dampening the investment ratio.
The blandishments include an increase in the foreign equity cap in critical
sectors. The first UPA budget, for 2004-05, had identified telecom, civil
aviation and insurance sectors as the ones in which the level of permissible
foreign equity holdings would increase. The FDI cap has already been lifted
in the civil aviation sector (from 40 to 49 percent), and on February
2 the government cleared a proposal to raise the FDI limit in telecom
from 49 to 74 percent. But these precisely are sectors where foreign investment
is not only unnecessary but positively harmful. In the case of telecom
moreover there are serious security considerations involved in having
majority foreign-owned companies. The idea seems more to give foreign
capital a finger in the profitable pie that is the Indian market, at a
time when metropolitan capital in these sectors is desperately looking
for outlets elsewhere, than to bring any benefits to the Indian economy.
The Left has been fiercely resisting these measures, but these unfortunately
do not need parliamentary approval.
Pension Funds
The latest move of the UPA government to let pension funds be used in
the stock-market and pensioners take the risk of loss, is yet another
"liberalization" measure with serious consequences for an extremely
vulnerable section of the population. But it is not just a matter of how
these funds are used. The 2005-06 budget permits the entry of FDI into
the pension sector. In effect therefore the government is planning to
hand over pension funds to MNCs for the purpose of speculating on the
stock-market.
The argument often advanced that the burden on the exchequer on account
of pension payment obligations is becoming too heavy is unacceptable.
It is the solemn duty of the government to meet whatever burden pension
payment obligations impose upon it, and it has to find the resources to
fulfill it. Considering the fact that 50 percent of the pension payment
obligations are on account of the armed forces, demurring at discharging
this duty is in particularly bad taste.
But then, even some well-meaning observers point out, since the pensioners
would be exposed to the possibility not just of losses but of gains as
well, they may even end up being much better off from the proposed measure.
Why should they object to it? The reasons are simple: first, any person
would be the most risk-averse when it is his or her pension funds which
are at stake; and secondly, the risks are far greater than usually supposed.
They arise not only from the fact that the stock market fluctuates wildly,
but also from the fact that the pensioners could well become victims of
unscrupulous speculators using their funds.
This last point is often missed: in a country like ours the political
empowerment of the people is far greater than their legal empowerment.
They have a much better chance of getting redress through political pressure
than they have of getting redress through legal action. They are safer
when their claims are with the State than they are when these claims are
on some private speculators. To leave pensioners to the mercy of a bunch
of speculators by allowing the latter to play the market with their funds
would be an almost criminal dereliction of duty on the part of the State
which the Left has rightly vowed to resist to the bitter end.
The Patent Amendment Act
There are two areas where the government has yielded some ground under
pressure from the Left. One is in the area of patents; and the other is
the current year"s budget. Let us examine these.
India had a Patent system introduced through an Act in 1970 which was
highly appreciated by progressive opinion all over the world. Among other
things it kept the prices of drugs low, and did so by not recognizing
product patents. No patentee in other words could prevent someone else
producing the same good using some process other than the one which had
been patented. This enabled the domestic production of drugs, which had
been developed abroad, by using a different process. Domestic substitutes
of drugs developed abroad could therefore be locally produced and sold
cheap. The TRIPS agreement under the WTO permitted product patents, and
allowed a 20 year life-span for patents compared to the 7 years under
the Indian Patents Act 1970. The WTO agreement which was signed without
taking the parliament"s prior permission, enjoined on India the obligation
to amend her Patents Act to make it TRIPS-compatible.
The WTO agreement however, like all international agreements, has provisions
and loopholes which could still be exploited to the benefit of the Indian
people while amending the 1970 Act for TRIPS-compatibility. In other words,
the term "TRIPS-compatibility" is itself a matter of interpretation,
and any government that is concerned with the welfare of the common people,
should naturally use an interpretation that safeguards their interests
to the maximum extent, even assuming the we have to fall in line over
"TRIPS-compatibility". But the NDA government brought in amendments
that showed scant respect for the people"s welfare and passed an
ordinance incorporating them. The UPA not only re-issued the ordinance,
but proposed an amended Act that was an exact carbon copy of the NDA"s
proposed legislation. This has been changed under pressure from the Left
and the amended Act, though TRIPS-compatible, protects the people much
better. To be sure the very introduction of product patents has deleterious
consequences, and in that sense any amendment of the 1970 Act is retrograde.
But within the framework of the WTO, the amended Act is much better than
the NDA/UPA Draft.
This becomes clear if we take a look at the demands made by a Peoples"
Commission which operated with the aim of getting the most out of the
existing TRIPS agreement. Its main demands were as follows:
"(i).. The term "invention" should be reserved for a "basic
novel product or process involving an inventive step and capable of industrial
application". All three criteria, "novelty", "inventive
step" and the quality of being "capable of industrial application",
must be insisted upon. (ii)…The proposed amendments allow patenting of
micro-organisms. This must not happen. Micro-organisms, including viruses,
should not be patented, and hence should also figure alongside plants
and animals, including seeds, varieties and species, in the list of non-patentable
items… (iii)… The proposed amendment provides no scope for compulsory
licensing in cases where, notwithstanding the offer of reasonable commercial
terms and conditions to the patent holder by an enterprise, the patentee
does not respond within a stipulated period of time. In all such cases
compulsory licensing is permitted even within the framework of TRIPS Article
31 (a) and (b), and countries like Brazil and China have passed legislation
allowing compulsory licensing. This omission from the proposed amendment
must be remedied forthwith. (iv) …In all cases where compulsory licenses
are granted, even though the production is supposed to be "predominantly"
for supply in the domestic market of the country in question, exporting
should also be explicitly allowed… (v) …Where applications have been received
during the transitional period 1.1.1995 to 31.12.2004, … patents, if granted,
would be effective from the latter date for a period of twenty years from
the date of application. In all such cases if any production activity
has been started by any enterprise during the transition period, then
that enterprise should be allowed to continue production on payment of
a nominal royalty to the patent-holder, after the patent has been granted,
instead being accused of violating the patent. (vi) …The magnitude of
royalty payment should be explicitly stipulated within a range, say 4-5
percent, of the sales turnover at ex-factory price. (vii) … Since the
TRIPS Agreement itself provides no explicit system of examination of any
pre-grant opposition to the grant of a patent, the existing provision
in the Indian Patents Act 1970, which is being sought to be amended, should
be retained."
It is noteworthy that all these suggestions, barring (ii) and (vi) were
incorporated in the amended draft of the Act owing to the Left"s
insistence, and that (ii) has been referred to an experts" committee.
At the same time however the necessity for mobilizing public opinion in
favour of a re-negotiation of the WTO, including in particular the TRIPS
agreement, remains. Unless a strong public opinion is built up the correlation
of political forces cannot be changed to a point where we can either reject
or go beyond the existing framework of the TRIPS agreement.
The
2005-06 Budget
The
2005-06 budget differed from other recent budgets both in its rhetoric
and in the somewhat larger allocations it made for social sectors and
rural development, including employment generation. The absolute amounts
involved of course were still very small, and even these small provisions
may not materialize if on account of tax shortfalls, which are bound to
arise this year, as they did last year, owing to the significant overestimation
of tax receipts in the budget, the Fiscal responsibility and Budgetary
Management Act comes into play and expenditures have to be scaled down.
Even so, the change is noteworthy.
This change however does not signify any shift away from the neo-liberal
package of policies. On the contrary many of its suggestions like opening
up the mining and pension sectors to foreign direct investment, encouraging
crop diversification at the expense of foodgrain self-sufficiency, the
reductions in customs duties on a range of capital goods, and the cut
in corporate income tax rate from 35 to 30 percent on domestic capitalists,
are all measures emanating from the neo-liberal perspective. And when
one adds to this the pronouncements of the Economic Survey on capital
account convertibility and on "labour market reform" (which
means in effect the institutionalization of the right to retrench), it
is clear that no change of direction away from neo-liberalism is being
contemplated.
Two questions immediately arise. First, how is it that within a regime
committed to neo-liberalism, additional financial resources have been
found for rural development and social sectors? The Finance Minister appears
to have given out substantial tax concessions all around and yet managed
to increase the Gross Budget Support for the Plan by 16.9 percent over
the previous year (BE to BE) and the Budget Support for the Central Plan
by 25.6 percent, even while ensuring a marginal reduction in the fiscal
deficit to 4.3 percent of the GDP. For a government that till the other
day kept asking "Where is the money?" when any worthwhile proposal
was mooted, including a universal EGA, this is a remarkable turnaround.
How has this become possible? Secondly, does the fact that the government
has made larger provision for rural development and social sectors while
remaining committed to a neo-liberal course suggest that we have finally
arrived at "liberalization with a human face", contradicting
the claim made above that the two cannot go together? Let us discuss these
seriatim.
The answer to the first question, about the source of financial resources,
is simple: the budget manages to balance its figures through substantial
"window dressing", both in the matter of the expected tax revenue
and in the matter of the expected fiscal deficit.
With the reduction in corporate tax rate, with the removal of a large
number of service providers from the purview of the service tax, with
the lightening of the income tax burden, with the reduction in customs
duties on a large number of items, especially capital goods, and with
significant concessions in the excise duties on several items, the Finance
minister's claim that his indirect tax proposals would be broadly revenue
neutral and that his direct tax proposals would garner Rs.6000 cr. extra,
appears untenable, notwithstanding the 50 paise cess on petrol and diesel,
and the slightly heavier taxation on "health hazard" goods.
But even if his claim is accepted, the tax revenue calculations still
appear grossly unrealistic. If we assume a generous 9 percent growth in
real terms of the non-agricultural sector during 2005-06, and a 6 percent
rate of inflation, the nominal growth rate of this sector comes to 15
percent. At existing tax rates the tax revenue cannot be expected to increase
at a rate much higher than this. And if additional tax revenue mobilization
is a small Rs.6000 cr., it follows that total tax revenue should also
increase at around 15 percent. Instead we find an expected tax revenue
increase, compared to 2004-05 (RE), of 21 percent, clearly an overestimate.
This would not matter if the Finance Minister chooses not to be tied down
by the FRBM, a silly piece of legislation as we have seen; but if he does,
then the positive features of the budget would be undermined.
The second area of "window-dressing" is with reference to the
fiscal deficit. There is a substantial "off-loading" of borrowing
from the budget to off-budget entities. At least three deserve mention.
The first is State governments. The Budget documents show what at first
glance appears a rather surprising reduction in total capital expenditure,
and correspondingly in the Gross Budgetary Support for the Plan. Plan
Expenditure for instance falls from Rs.145590 cr. last year to Rs.143497
cr. this year (BE to BE). The Finance Minister however claimed that the
Gross Budgetary Support (on a comparable definition to what was used earlier)
would be Rs.172500 cr. for 2005-06. The reason for this discrepancy lies
in the fact that following the Twelfth Finance Commission's report, State
governments would be borrowing around Rs.29000 cr. for their Plans from
the market. Earlier the Centre would have borrowed this amount and handed
it to the States, but now the States themselves would have to go the market.
This represents an offloading of the fiscal deficit from the Centre to
the States. In addition it is fraught with potentially serious consequences.
States may not be able to get the loans on reasonable terms, especially
in these financially "liberal" times (when even the captive
market for government and government-approved securities provided by the
Statutory Liquidity Ratio is being abandoned according to this year's
budget); some States may not be able to raise their loan requirements
from the market at all. True, the Centre which earlier had the sole prerogative
of market borrowing charged the States exorbitant rates on the loans it
provided to them; but the solution to that lies in regulating the rate
at which the Centre can lend to the States (pegging it for instance at
certain fixed percentage points below the average nominal growth rate
of the GDP) rather than having the States borrow directly from the market
which could even be a prelude to the fracturing of the nation's unity
(if States started borrowing freely from international agencies).
The second instance of implicit off-loading of the fiscal deficit is with
regard to the Infrastructure Development Fund, whose capital of Rs.10000
cr., which is supposed to provide "bridge finance" for infrastructure
projects that are remunerative economically but not financially, is not
provided for in the budget. Instead of borrowing directly, the government,
in other words, is making an agency set up by itself do the borrowing.
This borrowing, being off-budget, is not shown as part of the fiscal deficit.
The third instance is the absence of any reference to the food component
of the Employment Programmes in the budget documents. The 5 million tonnes
which the Finance Minister has promised as the food component of the Food
For Work programme and which does not figure in the budget will obviously
be loaned by the FCI to the FFW programme. A part of the fiscal deficit
is thus shifted out of the budget by making the FFW borrow from the FCI
instead of getting funds from the government which would have had to borrow
for the purpose.
For these reasons the actual fiscal deficit generated by the budgetary
provisions is much larger than what appears in the documents. One cannot
fault this in principle. On the contrary it only confirms the point that
the FRBM Act which forces the government to do such "off-loading"
of the fiscal deficit away from the budget to other government organizations
is a nuisance which even people like Mr.Chidambaram have come to realize.
But it is more than a nuisance. The practice of "off-loading"
which it implicitly encourages can have positively harmful implications.
For instance, such "off-loading" may, given the general neo-liberal
ethos, jeopardize the future of the agencies on to whose shoulders the
deficit is being off-loaded: State governments, as already mentioned,
might turn into proteges of agencies like the ADB and the World Bank (which
some of them are already in the process of becoming) under these circumstances.
This could damage the integrity of the nation. Likewise if the FCI's giving
loans to the FFW programme increases its own deficit (which is covered
through the food subsidy), then in the name of cutting the food subsidy
the same government might decide to wind up the FCI. In other words, enlarging
the fiscal deficit whether directly through the budget or through other
government agencies is fine provided a consistent approach of defending
the government agencies is simultaneously adopted.. But, one cannot be
sure of this.
Besides, while enlarging the fiscal deficit for incurring larger expenditure
is perfectly legitimate in a demand-constrained system, there is little
justification for doing so together with a reduction in corporate income
taxation. The argument that some parity has to be established between
personal income taxation and corporate income taxation has no basis whatsoever.
Hence the argument that since the highest rate of personal income tax
is 30 percent, the rate of corporate income tax must also be reduced to
30 percent from the current 35 percent lacks substance.
Indeed most of the tax concessions given in the budget lack any justification.
There is no reason why the scope of the service tax should be cut down
from its existing level. There is no reason why import duties should be
reduced on a variety of capital goods: while it would have a scarcely
noticeable effect on the overall investment, it would act to the detriment
of the domestic capital goods producers, causing a degree of de-industrialization
in this sector, which would also follow from the de-reservation of a number
of items hitherto reserved for the small-scale sector. Likewise, there
is also no reason for reducing the excise duties on a variety of luxury
goods like air-conditioners. And the reduction in import tariffs on a
range of agricultural goods is precisely the opposite of what the government
should be doing if it wished to undo the damage done to this sector by
neo-liberalism. Even experts like M.S.Swaminathan have been arguing that
agriculture cannot be treated like any other sector in the matter of protection,
since the livelihood of millions of peasants and labourers who have nowhere
else to go depends upon it. The budget alas pays scant heed to such sage
advice.
While these tax concessions are being given, the imposition of a cess
of 50 paise per litre on petrol and diesel appears uncalled for, especially
as it comes on top of price-hikes decreed very recently on these commodities.
The relief which the budget provides by way of reductions in import and
excise duties on kerosene and LPG would be offset to an extent by this
cess. In the case of petrol the net revenue raising effect is much less
than what appears at first sight since the government is a major consumer
of the commodity. In the case of diesel, any price hike jacks up transport
costs and has an across-the-board inflationary impact which should have
been avoided.
Two suggestions thrown out in the budget are a source of disquiet. The
first relates to the banking sector where the bounds on the Statutory
Liquidity Ratio and the Cash Reserve Ratio are sought to be removed and
the Reserve Bank made free to prescribe such prudential norms as it deems
fit. This entails giving greater autonomy to the RBI and making banks
free in their portfolio choice which would enable them to speculate more
freely. Both these, like the earlier pronouncement regarding making the
management of public sector banks more autonomous, are measures of financial
liberalization which would have adverse consequences for the economy.
The Finance Minister who talks of giving more credit to agriculture in
one breath, cannot advocate financial liberalization in the next without
inviting the charge of not being serious about the former objective.
The second disquieting suggestion relates to the entry of foreign direct
investment into mining and pension funds. The case of pension funds we
have already examined above. As regards mining, the argument against FDI
is obvious. Indeed, as Joan Robinson, the well-known Cambridge economistmentioned
earlier, had once remarked, of all the different areas of FDI involvement,
the mining sector is the worst, since minerals are an exhaustible resource.
The MNCs extract the mineral, ship the surplus back home, and leave when
the mine gets exhausted. But when that happens, the country is left high
and dry, with no more mineral resource left. The case of Myanmar illustrates
the point. At one time its oil wealth attracted much foreign investment
(Burma-Shell), and it experienced for a brief period an enormous boom,
when oil extraction was going on. But today, with its oil wealth exhausted,
it is one of the forty "least developed" countries in the world.
There is absolutely no argument whatsoever for inducting MNCs into the
mining sector.
This brings us to our second question: is the budget an embodiment of
"liberalization with a human face"? The fact that patently neo-liberal
measures are being contemplated by a Finance Minister who has ostensibly
shown concern for the poor, only demonstrates that this budget is an attempt
to please all, the MNcs, the corporate sector, the salariat and, to an
extent the poor and those who speak for them. Such a "please-all"
budget can only be based on a degree of arithmetical jugglery and hence
can only be a transitory phenomenon. Or putting it differently, this budget
does not mark the ushering in of a "growth-with-equity" trajectory,
or of "liberalization with a human face". It rather represents
a temporary tactical compromise, a tactical adjustment in the march along
a neo-liberal path, which has been necessitated by the relentless pressure
exerted on the "liberalizers" by the Left.
Concluding
Observations
The
last few months of the functioning of the UPA government reveal clearly
the bind in which it is caught. It cannot openly discard the Common Minimum
Programme to which it is ostensibly committed; it cannot push ahead with
impunity with the neo-liberal programme which international finance capital
enjoins upon it. Its attempts to browbeat the Left to allow it to discard
the CMP for a neo-liberal programme have failed. Some bourgeois commentators,
impatient with this situation, have even started flying kites about a
"grand coalition" between the Congress and the BJP, which in
effect means a "grand coalition" between sections drawn from
both these Parties. What these commentators fail to understand is that
even if such a grand coalition were to come about, which is a tall order
anyway, it would not get the mandate of the people who have expressed
their rejection of neo-liberal policies in the May elections. The bind
of the government is really the outward manifestation of an interregnum,
a stand-off between the forces aligned to international finance capital
on the one hand and the popular forces on the other. As the latter become
more organized, conscious and effective, the present situation would change
in a more favourable direction for the progressive movement.
|