The
global recession is still very much with us, despite the recent attempts
by media and some policy makers especially in the North to dismiss it
as almost over, and to find some indications of the ''green shoots''
of recovery in almost each item of economic and financial news. But
even as the downturn continues to cause trade flows to decline, and
jobs to be lost, some analysts are already talking about the fears of
a major inflationary spiral once the global economy recovers.
Most of those who are raising this concern are those who were opposed
to countercyclical economic policy measures in the first place. When
governments in the developed world, and especially in the US, came up
relatively rapidly with measures to provide huge bailouts to ease bank
lending in the face of the severe credit crunch and lower interest rates,
such critics argued that this would release too much liquidity into
the system and therefore eventually create inflation.
They were even more opposed to fiscal expansion and running large deficits
to combat the liquidity trap conditions that seemed to have emerged
in core capitalist economies. They insisted (and some like the German
Chancellor Angela Merkel continue to insist) that such a strategy would
simply generate more inflation. There was an implicit, usually unstated,
concern that the positive effects of fiscal expansion would leak out
through imports so that other economies would benefit rather than those
in which the fiscal expansion occurs.
There are some obvious flaws to such an argument, which fundamentally
indicates a monetarist approach to economic policy. In situations of
unemployment and excess capacity, government spending creates new effective
demand that then generates more output through a multiplier process.
Therefore new demand is met by new supply, and this creates an output
response rather than the price response that is expected by monetarists.
It is only in conditions of full employment, or where there is some
supply bottleneck that prevents the multiplier process from running
its course, that any inflation would result. In any case, the spectre
facing the world a few months ago was one of generalised deflation,
or falling prices, and this still seems to be happening in most major
economies. So this argument was misplaced.
However, while the basic premises of the monetarist argument are wrong,
this does not mean that the threat of future inflation can be completely
discounted. In fact, it can be argued that even without a complete revival
of the global economy, and even as wage incomes throughout the world
continue to fall, there may be upward pressure on certain prices in
the near future. In particular, global commodity prices - especially
those of oil and food - may well increase again in the next couple of
year.
The reasons for this possibility are very different from those offered
by monetarists. They are not even related to possible imbalances between
global demand and supply. Instead, they reflect the continuing possibility
that financial speculation can cause sharp changes in the prices of
commodities in the world market.
Financial deregulation in the early part of the current decade, especially
in the US, gave a major boost to the entry of new financial players
into the commodity exchanges, and allowed unregulated activity in commodity
futures markets, which became a new avenue for speculative activity.
The result was excessive volatility displayed by important commodities
like oil, minerals, food and other cash crops over 2007 and 2008. As
more purely financial players entered these markets in search of quick
capital gains, prices in the futures markets soared and drove up spot
prices, in a process completely the opposite of the risk-hedging role
that futures markets are supposed to play. The subsequent sharp declines
in prices were also related to changes in financial markets, in particular
the need of financial agents for liquidity to cover losses elsewhere.
These price changes did not reflect real demand and supply at all, since
both scarcely changed over the year.
In food items, such volatility had very adverse effects on both cultivators
and consumers. It sent out confusing, misleading and often completely
wrong price signals to farmers that caused over-sowing in some phases
and under-cultivation in others. Also, while the pass-through of global
prices was extremely high in developing countries in the phase of rising
prices, the reverse tendency has not occurred as global prices have
fallen. Both cultivators and food consumers lost out because of extreme
price instability, and the only gainers were the financial speculators
who were able to profit from rapidly changing prices.
The problem is that, despite the unfortunate lessons delivered by the
functioning of financial and commodity markets in the past two years,
the moves towards more effective regulation are still hesitant and inadequate.
Even the recent document released by the Obama administration in the
US on financial sector reform does not adequately come to grips with
the need to control commodity futures markets and prevent the kind of
speculative activity that has caused so much damage.
Meanwhile, it is also the case that banks and other financial players
are once again awash with liquidity and looking for profitable avenues
to invest in. Commodity markets are once again ripe to be invaded by
such players. And prices in such markets can be talked up not only by
such investment but also by pliant international financial media. If
there are any short term supply reductions in any major grain market,
some poor harvests because of adverse weather conditions and so on,
the chances are that prices in such markets will rise much more and
faster than is warranted by any supply shortfall. This will be because
of speculation, but once again it will have very detrimental effects
on the real economy, especially in the developing world. And such price
rises will then force governments to focus on inflation control rather
than real economy revival.