The
nature of financial integration of developing countries with their developed
counterparts has been radically transformed over the last four years.
Evidence collated by the World Bank's annual report for 2007 on Global
Development Finance, reveal a number of features of the new scenario
that have far-reaching implications.
The first of these is an acceleration of financial flows to developing
countries (Chart 1) precisely during the years when as a group they
have been characterised by rising surpluses on their current account.
Total flows touched a record estimated 600 billion in 2006, having risen
by 19 per cent on top of an average growth of 40 per cent during the
three previous years. Relative to the GDP of these countries, total
flows, at 5.1 per cent, are at levels they touched at the time of the
East Asian financial crisis in 1997.
A second feature is the acceleration of the long term tendency for private
flows to dominate over official (bilateral and multilateral) flows.
Private debt and equity inflows, which had risen by 50 per cent a year
over the three years ending 2005, increased a further 17 per cent in
2006 to touch a record $647 billion (Chart 2). On the other hand net
official lending has in fact declined over the last two years. One factor
accounting for this is the failure of the G-7 to match promises of a
substantial hike in aid disbursements beyond what the retirement of
the debt of few heavily indebted poor countries ensures. The other is
that the more developed among the developing countries have chose to
make advance repayments of debt owed to official creditors, especially
the IMF and the World Bank. Overall, principal repayments to official
creditors exceeded disbursements by $70 billion in 2005 and $75 billion
in 2006. In the event there has been a reverse flow of capital to the
World Bank and the IMF, which is threatening the viability and influence
of these institutions, especially the latter. However, the increase
in private flows has more than matched the reverse flows to official
creditors.
The
third feature is that the dominance of private flows has meant that
both equity and debt flows to developing countries have risen rapidly,
with the surge being greater in the case of the former. Net private
debt and equity flows to developing countries have risen from a little
less that $170 billion in 2002 to close to $647 billion in 2006, an
almost four-fold increase over a four-year period. While net private
equity flows, that rose from $163 billion to $419 billion dominated
the surge, net private debt flows too increased rapidly. Bond issues
rose from $10.4 billion to $49.3 billion and borrowing from international
banks from $2.3 billion to a huge $112.2 billion. What is more, net
short-term debt, outflows of which tend to trigger financial crises,
has risen from around half a billion in 2002 to $72 billion in 2006.
The fourth feature, which is a corollary of these developments, is that
there is a high degree of concentration of flows to developing countries,
implying excess exposure in a few countries. Ten countries (out of 135)
accounted for 60 per cent of all borrowing during 2002-04, and that
proportion has risen subsequently to touch three-fourths in 2006. In
the portfolio equity market, flows to developing countries were directed
at acquiring a share in equity either through the secondary market or
by buying into initial public offers (IPOs). IPOs dominated in 2006,
accounting for $53 billion of the $96 billion inflow. But here too there
were signs of concentration. Four of the 10 largest IPOs were by Chinese
companies, accounting for two-thirds of total IPO value. Another 3 of
those 10 were by Russian companies, accounting for an additional 22
per cent of IPO value.
A fifth feature is that despite this rapid rise in developing country
exposure, with that exposure being excessively concentrated in a few
countries, the market is still overtly optimistic. Ratings upgrades
dominate downgrades in the bond market. And bond market spreads are
at unusual lows. This optimism indicates that risk assessments are pro-cyclical,
underestimating risk when investments are booming, and overestimating
risks when markets turn downwards. But two consequences are the herding
of investors in developing country markets and their willingness to
invest in a larger volume of money in risky, unrated instruments.
Finally, the rapid rise in capital flows to developing countries at
a time when many of them are recording large current account surpluses
has substantially increased their foreign exchange reserves and triggered
a flow of capital out of developing countries. This outflow takes three
forms: (i) investment of reserves in safe and low-return instruments
such as US Treasury Bills; (ii) financing of asset acquisition to support
the growing presence of leading developing country firms in global commodity
markets; and (iii) financial investments in and lending to other developing
countries, resulting in the South-South flow of capital. These trends
together suggest that developing countries are still largely restricted
to the low return or high risk segments of global capital flow. This
is the cost they bear to meet the requirements of ensuring balance in
the global balance of payments.
These features of the current global financial scenario can be interpreted
in two ways. One is in the direction taken by the World Bank. It admits,
on the one hand, that ''the probability of a turn in the credit cycle''
has risen and that a ''key challenge facing developing countries is
to manage the transition by taking pre-emptive measures aimed at lessening
the risk of a sharp, unexpected reversal in capital flows''. On the
other, it downplays the dangers involved by arguing that the surge in
capital flows ''speaks well for the resiliency of developing economies
and for the ability of international financial markets to manage risks.''
An alternative view would be that many emerging market economies that
attract a disproportionate share of these capital flows, are fast approaching
a situation where they are vulnerable to financial crises, with the
current scenario incorporating features that could make these crises
more intense. What is more, it appears that prudential norms, risk management
techniques and disclosure requirements put in place as part of the so-called
''new international financial architecture'' seem inadequate to foreclose
a build up of this kind. This is not surprising, since garnering large
and quick profits rather than minimising risks seems to be the dominant
requirement of financial institutions from the developed countries.
The current situation is the inevitable result of expanding the space
for financial capital through dilution or elimination of regulation.
Financial liberalisation has ensured that since the late 1970s, the
newly discovered ''emerging markets'' among developing countries have
been the new frontier for profiteering by global financial institutions.
Awash with the liquidity derived from the surpluses earned by oil exporters
and the savings accumulated by the generation of baby-boomers in the
West, banks, investment funds and pension funds were looking to new
avenues for lucrative investments. The role of financial intermediaries
was one of dressing up developing countries that were hitherto ''untouchables''
as lucrative destinations for financial capital. And financial innovation
consisted in not just identifying instruments that could carry such
investments, but derivatives that could help hedge against the risk
associated with rushing into uncharted territory.
The process began when developing countries were still reeling under
the effects of declining non-fuel commodity prices and rising oil prices,
which had left gaping holes in the current account of their balance
of payments. The new found interest of global finance offered developing
country governments an opportunity to finance that gap, even if it meant
offering high returns to foreign financial investors. It was this conflation
of interests of developing country governments and financial institutions
from the developed countries that led up to the debt crisis of the 1980s
and the financial crises of the 1990s, including those that began with
the East Asian crises in 1997.
One consequence of the 1997 crisis was a sharp decline in lending to
developing countries. But this did not mean a decline in capital flows.
Rather, encouraged by the post-crisis deflation in asset prices in emerging
markets and the sharp devaluation of their currencies, foreign direct
investment kept flowing into developing countries to acquire assets
at rock bottom prices when measured in hard currencies. While net debt
flows to developing countries declined from $53.1 billion in 1998 to
just $1.2 billion in 2000, net FDI flows remained more or less stable
at around $170 billion a year.
Since 2002, when growth accelerated or remained high in China and India
and commodity prices rose sharply in the case of oil and metals and
moderately in the case of agriculture, this lull in capital flows has
given way to a surge. Besides the features noted above, three kinds
of developments have accompanied this surge. First, the growing importance
of unregulated hedge funds looking for abnormal returns in portfolio
equity markets, which renders activity in those markets highly speculative
and opaque. Second, the rapid increase in investments by ''private equity''
firms – investing largely in unlisted equity - in corporations in developing
countries. The size of each of these investments is such that they are
identified as foreign ''direct'' investments, even though their objective
is speculative. The evidence on the controversial role played by these
firms in the developed countries indicates that their activity too is
extremely opaque. Third, the revival once again of the global market
for developing country debt, driven this time by private corporate borrowing
in the syndicated loan market. Since this new surge in credit rides
on a wave of securitisation that transfers the risk associated with
such lending to pension and mutual funds among others, accumulating
risk does not serve as a deterrent on banks creating such credit.
There are a number of implications of these tendencies. To start with,
the risk associated with the current surge in capital flows can be and
is much greater than was true during previous episodes involving a similar
surge. Moreover, the surge is accompanied by the growing acquisition
of assets in developing countries outside the stock market with objectives
that are largely speculative, so that a sell-off, if it occurs, would
be far more widespread. And the persistence of the herd instinct has
meant that the surge in fixed and portfolio investment flows has resulted
in a revival of credit flows that is unbridled since it is accompanied
by risk-mitigation techniques that transfer risk to those who are least
equipped to assess them. Unfortunately, all of this occurs in an environment
in which the target of both investment and debt flows is the private
sector, which makes it difficult for governments that have liberalised
financial regulation to control such flows. In sum, the risks associated
with the current surge in capital flows are far greater than emerges
from the World Bank's rather sanguine assessment of the possible fall-out
of the ongoing transformation of global financial flows. A turn in the
investment cycle, with far-reaching implications, is real and imminent.