The
ghost called inflation is back to haunt the government. Inflation was
the country's Problem No. 1 for much of India's post-Independence history.
But since the mid-1990s the problem seemed to have gone away. Not only
did the annual rate of inflation measured on a point-to-point basis
decline quite sharply to below five percent, but food grain and foreign
exchange stocks accumulating with the government made the task of managing
any inflationary threat seem like child's play.
Recently, however, inflation seems to have once again become an issue.
It all began with reports from the ground that retail prices of many
essentials like pulses and vegetables were rising, though the official
wholesale price indices (WPI) were not reflecting the trend. Then came
the news that the tendency had begun to affect staples like wheat. These
''straws in the wind'' became a cause for concern when it emerged that
government stocks of cereals were depleting, the harvest was not as
good as expected and procurement was way below target. Finally, the
official WPI began signalling a potential crisis.
The last of these facts needs explication. Even the most recent wholesale
price indices relating to the week-ending June 10 (released on June
23) do not point to a disconcertingly high overall rate of inflation.
According to those figures, aggregate inflation on an annual point-to-point
basis, stood at just 5.24 per cent, which is well below the 8-10 per
cent rate that signalled a problem in the past.
There are two reasons for this. First, the ''system'', long-accustomed
to low inflation, now seems less inflation-tolerant. Taking a cue from
international policy trends, the financial media is already predicting
a rise in interest rates-an expectation that has been endorsed by the
Reserve Bank of India's words and deeds in recent months. Inflation,
it is argued, is a sign that the system is ''oveheating'' with-in layman's
parlance-''too much money chasing too few goods''. This is seen to require
a hike in interest rates to curb debt-financed investment and consumption
spending. And, as expected, the yield on government bonds, which leads
the trend in overall interest rates, has been rising. The yield on benchmark
10-year Central Government bonds has risen to a four-year high of 8.13
per cent.
The problem here is that higher interest rates are what the ''system''
fears most. As has often been noted in this column, India's 7-8 per
cent rate of growth, which the government wants to raise to 9-10 per
cent, is based on the availability of plenty of cheap money. That spurs
debt-financed consumption spending and housing investment. It also allows
corporations to restructure their debt, reducing interest costs, raising
profits and spurring investment in sunrise sectors. A rise in interest
rates could put the brake on the debt-financed growth spiral.
Low interest rates also support the stock market boom, which has been
misrepresented to be a sign of a healthy economy. As the recent downturn
in global and Indian stock markets shows, higher interest rates, or
even the expectations of a rise, can badly damage the confidence of
financial investors, drive stock prices down and wipe out large volumes
of illusive paper wealth. The reason is simple-a lot of speculative
investment that inflates the stock bubble is financed with debt. If
interest rates rise to make it less profitable to borrow and bet, these
speculators pull out, depressing stock prices and eroding the value
of indices misused as symbols of economic health. Thus expected or actual
increases in interest rates are a threat to the ostensibly successful
trajectory of growth based on debt-financed spending and symbolised
by stock market buoyancy that the UPA government celebrates.
The second reason why an aggregate inflation rate of 5 per cent plus
is providing cause for concern is that the aggregate conceals significant
variations in the rate of price inflation across commodities, with some
essentials registering particularly high price increases. According
to reports, in the middle of week-ending June 23, spot prices of pulses
like chickpea (chana) and black gram (urad) in Delhi's markets have
risen by 40 and 70 per cent respectively, when compared with a year
back. Prices of vegetables like tomato are soaring in retail and whole
sale markets. And, more recently, wheat prices have also been on the
rise, with spot prices having risen by close to 14 per cent when compared
with the corresponding date of the previous year.
These differentials are visible in the recently released WPI figures
as well, with the point-to-point rate of inflation between 11 June 2005
and 10 June 2006 varying from as low as 2.9 per cent in the case of
manufactured products to between 9 and 10 per cent in the case of wheat,
fuel and sugar and finally to as much as 35 per cent in the case of
pulses. Since the commodities subject to excessive price increases,
though few in number, are largely essential consumption goods, inflation
has re-emerged as a problem even when the average rate of inflation
stands at just 5.2 per cent.
Point-to-point
inflation from 11 June 2005 to 10 June 2006
|
All
Commodities
|
5.2
|
Manufactured
Products
|
2.9
|
Foodgrains |
9.5
|
Cereals |
6.1
|
Wheat |
10.3
|
Rice |
2.2
|
Pulses |
34.7
|
Fruits
and Vegetables |
2.9
|
Fuel
Power Light and Lubricants |
9.9
|
Sugar |
9.7
|
Source:
Office of the Economic Advisor, Ministry of Industry
|
With the WPI beginning to reflect these trends, the government has decided
to act, by exploiting the cushion offered by the large foreign exchange
reserves available with the central bank. On the day before the public
release of the latest WPI figures, it decided to permit freer import of
specific commodities at lower rates of customs duties, on the grounds
that increased domestic supply based on imports would help dampen domestic
price increases. While an extension of the decision taken in February
to import wheat to shore up depleting government stocks, the more recent
announcement goes much further. It permits private actual users of wheat
like flour millers, biscuit manufacturers and bread makers to import wheat
duty free till the next rabi harvest. It has allowed customs duty-free
import of sugar till the beginning of the next crushing season which starts
in October. And it has put a ban on exports of pulses. All these are expected
to augment domestic supply and dampen inflationary price expectations.
This knee-jerk reaction to use imports or reduced exports as a weapon
against inflation is of course based on the premise that international
prices rule below domestic prices and that inflation is the result of
inadequate domestic supply. Neither of this is necessarily true. Thus,
sugar mill owners have claimed that duty-free imports of the commodity
would have no effect either on domestic supply or prices, because the
landed cost of imported sugar is at Rs.23-24 a kg well above the domestic
price of Rs.18 a kg. And exports of pulses in 2004-05 stood at just 2.4
lakh tonnes, whereas imports touched 12.96 lakh tonnes.
The more important issue is whether the government's move addresses the
real causes of recent inflationary trends. There are a number of such
causes. The first of these is the poor agricultural production performance.
While inadequate purchasing power may have prevented this from being translated
into a situation of supply shortage relative to demand, this is a problem
that needs addressing. But the focus of the government's agricultural
policy has been that of enhancing credit to agriculture. However, credit
has often proved more a problem than a solution, since returns to farmers
are inadequate to meet repayment commitments, as reflected by the spate
of suicides by debt-encumbered farmers. Moreover, small and medium farmers
are often unable to access credit even when it is available in principle.
What is needed is to increase public investment in agriculture-a policy
alternative precluded by the government's refusal to garner more taxes
and its commitment to sharply reduce its budgetary deficit.
Second, removal of controls on the movements of agricultural commodities,
liberalisation of rules relating to the operation of private traders and
agribusiness firms and the failure to procure adequate amounts at the
minimum support price has resulted in a situation where stocks with the
private trade are rising while those with the government are increasingly
eroded. This has encouraged speculative hoarding at the first sign of
an indifferent harvest, resulting in price increases. Speculation, rather
than an actual supply-demand imbalance seems to be the problem.
Finally, complacence over inflation has prevented the government from
exploiting options available for absorbing the effect of the rise in international
oil prices, resulting in an engineered increase in prices resulting from
increases in the prices of universal intermediates like petrol and diesel.
In sum, the problem is not one of excess demand in all cases but of manipulated
shortages and cost-driven inflation. By trying to deal with these problems
with easier imports the government is only increasing its dependence on
foreign finance to manage domestic inflation, since it is the availability
of such finance that makes enhanced imports an option at a time when the
country's trade deficit is widening. It is not clear whether such a policy
would be successful. And even if it is, it would imply that the returns
to domestic farming would be eroded further, aggravating the long-term
deceleration in the rate of growth of agricultural
production. Dependence on foreign finance and a worsening of the agrarian
crisis seem to be the costs of using imports to exorcise the ghost called
inflation.
|