On
June 24, Union Petroleum Minister, Jaipal Reddy, announced a package
of measures relating to oil prices. Prices of the more ''sensitive''
oil products like diesel, kerosene and LPG were raised, while customs
and excise duties on these products were reduced or scrapped. The
latter was ostensibly aimed at reducing the impact of the price
increase on the final consumer by absorbing a part of the increase
in the form of reduced government revenues. Yet, in the city of
Delhi, for example, prices of diesel rose from Rs. 37.75 a litre
to Rs. 40.75 a litre, that of kerosene from Rs. 12.73 to Rs. 14.73
a litre and that of LPG from Rs. 345.35 a cylinder to Rs. 395.35
a cylinder.
This could not have occurred at a worse time. Inflation is already
running at close to double-digit levels. Oil is a universal input
that directly and indirectly enters into the cost of production
of every other commodity. So the increases announced would have
direct and indirect cost-push effects that are likely to aggravate
inflationary trends.
It is to be expected that the direct and indirect impact of these
increases would substantially erode the real (inflation-adjusted)
income of the ''common man''. As far as the ordinary citizen is
concerned, oil price increases that have little to do with costs
of production are a tax used by the government to adjust to an international
shock. Since that tax falls even on the poor it is ''regressive''.
The refusal to look for alternative measures to protect the real
incomes of the poor and to persist with the desire to follow prices
in global markets at any cost is reflective of a deep policy inertia
that damages the less well-to-do. This is not a government that
seeks to govern on behalf of its people, but merely one that follows
the dictates of those who control and manipulate markets.
By opting for the oil price increases the UPA was sending out many
implicit messages. The first is the signal that, despite the government's
complete failure to bring inflation under control, the economists
that run it are unwilling to give on their conviction that domestic
oil prices must be calibrated to reflect international ''market''
prices. Those ''market'' prices are, of course, influenced by a
whole host of factors that textbook markets are not supposed to
harbour. These include: price setting by a cartel that tries, however
unsuccessfully, to control global supply; political and strategic
developments in West Asia that are not unrelated to the fact that
the region houses much of the world's oil reserves that countries
like the US covet; and, the growing presence of speculators, whose
activities in futures markets affect the spot prices of crude and
oil products.
The second message comes from the timing of the increase. The government
clearly knew that these measures would be unpopular and would intensify
inflationary trends. Hence, it chose to wait till the elections
to the legislatures in four important states had been completed
before adopting them. That is, the government is making clear that
measures such as these were in its view ''unavoidable'' even if
they are damaging and unpopular. Policy inertia in the face of inflation
is not because the government disagrees with opposition assessments
of the outcome of its actions, but because it seriously believes
that there is no alternative to adjusting oil prices upwards when
world prices rise.
It must be noted here that if the action is presented as one of
merely adjusting oil prices to keep pace with changes in international
prices, then prices should be adjusted downwards when international
prices fall. This does happen occasionally, but there is an element
of asymmetry involved. The government is more keen on raising domestic
prices when international prices rise, but less concerned with reducing
domestic prices when the latter fall.
Even if it is true, as it argues, that the government cannot avoid
responding to the large increases in international oil prices, the
question remains whether a sharp hike in retail prices is the best
response. It is true that government inaction would mean that the
burden of the divergence between changes in the international price
of oil and in the domestic prices of oil products would fall solely
on the three oil marketing companies (Indian Oil Corporation, Hindustan
Petroleum Corporation Limited and Bharat Petroleum Corporation Limited).
While estimates vary, official projections of losses that would
be incurred due to revenue shortfalls from sale of diesel, kerosene
and domestic LPG place them at Rs. 166,172 crore. The oil marketing
companies claim they were losing Rs. 15.44 a litre on diesel, Rs.
27.47 a litre on kerosene and Rs. 381.14 on the sale of every 14.2-kg
domestic LPG cylinder. If they were not compensated in some way,
their viability was at stake.
The real issue was the degree to which the government should rely
on any of the five different alternatives available to it when adjusting
to what is an oil shock generated by a combination of conflict-induced
supply shortfalls, rising demand and rampant speculation. These
alternatives are that of: (i) raising retail prices; (ii) reducing
customs and excise duties even with unchanged retail prices, so
to transfer the benefits of the duty reduction to the oil marketing
companies; (iii) generating revenues by taxing the super profits
of the oil companies that are involved in the production and export
of crude at the current high prices, so as to compensate the marketing
companies; (iv) generating resources through additional taxes on
or lower tax concessions for India's super-rich individuals and
the corporate sector, so as to pay for subsidies that protect the
ordinary consumer against the effects of the global oil price shock;
and (v) borrowing money through the issue of oil bonds to compensate
the oil marketing companies for their losses.
The principle to determine which agency or agencies should bear
the burden of an increase in international oil prices, and to what
extent, was examined by a committee headed by C. Rangarajan. The
committee spent much of its energies on the different stages through
which imported and domestic crude is converted into petroleum products
supplied to the consumer, and the cost escalation that arises as
the raw material passes through these stages. Through that analysis,
it found that the upstream oil companies (or oil companies other
than the oil marketing companies, such as ONGC, OIL and GAIL) had
in some years recorded significant profits; that the oil industry
contributed substantially to the central exchequer through duties,
taxes, royalty, dividends etc.; and that the petroleum sector alone
contributed around two-fifths of the total net excise revenues of
the Centre. In Delhi, for example, central and state taxes amounted
to 38 and 17 per cent respectively of the retail price of petrol
and 23 and 11 per cent respectively of diesel. The incidence of
taxes as a proportion of the retail price in India was higher than
in the US, Canada, Pakistan, Nepal, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka, though
they were lower than in many countries in Europe known for their
higher average level of prices. In sum, there was an adequate buffer
to shield domestic consumers from the effects of the increase in
international prices, so long as segments that can afford to take
a cut in petroleum-related revenues because they have alternative
sources of resource mobilisation, are willing to accept such a reduction.
By all accounts it is the Centre and firms controlled by it which
are currently in that position.
The government claims that it is relying on a combination of available
measures to reduce the burden imposed on the consumer. Thus according
to its calculations the ''modest'' price increases would reduce
under-recoveries by just Rs. 29,000 crore, while the loss to the
government because of the duty cuts was as much as Rs. 49,000 crore,
consisting of Rs. 26,000 crore from customs duties and Rs. 23,000
core from excise duties.
The difficulty is that the price hike finally imposed is by no means
''moderate'' and its effects come when the ordinary citizen is already
shouldering the burden of rising inflation. What would have been
more sensible and fair was to opt for a combination of the other
four means of adjusting to the oil shocks, so as to keep prices
constant. The government did reduce duties on petroleum products,
but only by a small amount. But this was not any special manoeuvre.
Since the government imposes ad valorem or duties specified as a
proportion of the landed cost of imports (in the case of customs
duties) or of the price of the product (in the case of excise duties),
when those prices rise so do the government's revenues, delivering
a bonanza to the state. Thus, when official spokesmen quote a revenue
loss figure like Rs. 49,000 crore, the ''loss'' is only notional.
It reflects the revenue forgone relative to that which would have
been garnered if duties had not been cut. It does not necessarily
reflect a shortfall in revenues relative to some normative target.
In fact revenues are likely to be higher than any such target sine
the reduction in duties does not wipe out the additional taxes that
the government collects because of the price increase.
Not surprisingly, one of the recommendations of the committee on
oil pricing headed by C. Rangarajan was that the Centre should shift
out of ad valorem excise duties (revenues from which rise with prices)
and fix the central excise duty at a specific rate. This recommendation
has been largely ignored.
But, the government has in the past too adjusted duty downwards
when prices rose. Thus, a few years back, the government similarly
dropped the then prevailing 5 per cent customs duty on crude oil,
and reduced the customs duty on petrol and diesel from 7.5 per cent
to 2.5 per cent and the customs duty on other petroleum products
from 10 per cent to 5 per cent. But, as noted, in order to benefit
from the revenue buoyancy induced by increases in oil prices, the
government has most often not cutback on duty rates adequately or
has avoided such cuts. Further, taxes are reintroduced or revised
upwards when prices fall.
The use of petrol and diesel as sources of tax revenues has meant
that the retail prices of these products include a substantial duty
component. Prior to the 2008 duty adjustment and price hike the
tax component in the retail prices of petrol and diesel was placed
at 53 and 34 per cent respectively. If the government had in the
past chosen to forego this revenue completely, but kept the retail
price at its earlier tax-inclusive level, the losses of the oil
marketing companies would have been much less. These losses could
have been substantially compensated for with additional taxes and
a dose of borrowing in the context of an emergency.
The real issue then is whether the government can afford to lose
the windfall revenues it obtains in the form of taxes on oil. Could
those losses have been compensated with additional taxes on and
reduced tax concessions to those companies, businesses and individuals
who have benefited hugely from the high growth of recent years?
The argument of the opposition is that this could have easily been
done and they have offered many suggestions. They are indeed right.
If the government chose to ignore their suggestions it must be because
it believes that taxing the rich to pay for protection against the
oil shock for the poor and middle classes is not acceptable.
Rather than look to such options the UPA government in Delhi has
adopted a cynical posture. It has called upon cash-strapped state
governments to reduce the sales taxes they impose on oil products
to moderate the impact of the price hike on retail prices. This
would involve a reduction in specific or ad valorem sales taxes
levied on diesel and LPG. With many Congress state governments being
forced into complying with what for them is a central directive,
and allies like the Trinamul Congress reducing duties to sell their
pro-poor image, pressure builds on other states to do the same.
This amounts to getting the state governments to implement policies
that the Central government is unwilling to adopt itself. Moreover,
it amounts to the use by the Congress of the control it exercises
over a few state governments to create a political atmosphere where
popular anger against the price hike is turned against opposition-controlled
state governments and deflected away from the Centre.
Thus, at the margin it is the consumer and the state governments
who have been called upon to carry the additional burden. Neoliberal
policy makers at the Centre must have their way even if that badly
damaged the economic position of the already beleaguered states
and the ordinary citizen. The reason clearly is to appeal to sections
such as finance, which want constant reassurance that the logic
of markets will drive the system. The argument used is that if economic
rationality is violated, capital will leave the country. What is
forgotten is that inflation, which market friendly pricing unleashes,
erodes the real value of financial assets. So finance capital may
choose to exit anyway.
* This article was originally published in
the Frontline Volume 28-Issue 15, July 16-29, 2011.