A
study recently conducted by the Naandi Foundation in India has found
that 42 per cent of children under five years of age were severely
or moderately underweight because of inadequate access to nutrition.
The study was based on a survey of the height and weight of more than
one lakh children across six states of the country. To restate its
central result: more than two in every five children below five years
of age in this country do not get even the basic minimum nutrition
to survive or develop normally.
Releasing the report, the Prime Minister declared this this was a
''national shame''. Nobody can disagree. Child undernutrition of this
magnitude after close to 65 years of independent national development
is indeed a shame. And what is even more shameful is that in the period
over the last twenty years, when India was reportedly ''shining''
because GDP growth had risen significantly, this failure could not
be adequately addressed. Income growth accelerated, but the decline
in the level of malnutrition was unsatisfyingly slow. That evidence
has also forced the PM to recognise that despite impressive growth
in national product in recent years, the level of malnutrition in
the country had remained unacceptably high.
Given the obsession with GDP growth of the UPA government, this recognition
that growth does not deliver even basic nutrition is indeed positive.
But for those who have been observing the path of development India
has pursued, especially since the 1990s, such evidence is by no means
surprising. The evidence is common knowledge, as are the policies
that can help address the problem.
There are many tendencies involved here that need to be separated
to correctly understand the predicament the country faces. The first
is of course the fundamental problem that capitalist accumulation
driven by the search for profit never distributes justly the fruits
of whatever growth it delivers. The rich grow richer but the poor
tend to either lose out or gain only marginally from the additions
to national income. Widespread malnutrition despite growth is one
of the consequences. That tendency is exaggerated when the capitalism
that we speak of emerges and develops in an environment where social
and structural backwardness persists. Hence, rapid advances in human
development, be it in terms of reduction in poverty, elimination of
hunger and malnutrition or lessening of social deprivation, are never
seen.
Thus, it is not surprising to see that improvements in social indicators
and reduction in malnutrition are not directly associated with GDP
growth or the level of GDP. Within India, for example, Sikkim reported
the lowest rates of child malnutrition, while richer Madhya Pradesh
had the highest. And, according to one source, the percentage of under
weight children in Gujarat, one of India's richest and fast growing
state, marginally increased between 2001 and 2006 to touch as much
as 47 per cent.
Similarly, for a range of reasons, there are substantial differences
in the improvement in social indicators across countries. 28 out of
37 countries in poor Sub-Saharan Africa have lower levels of per capita
income than India. Yet they are characterised by lower levels of child
malnutrition than India. The failure in India to implement land reform
and reduce asset concentration, combined with the pernicious effects
of caste-based exclusion, has resulted in forms of extreme inequality
that ensure that large numbers remain nutritionally deprived even
as India's income grows.
The problem is not confined to children. As economist A.K. Shiv Kumar
notes: ''Birth weights of less than 2,500 grams are very closely associated
with poor growth not just in infancy but throughout childhood. Estimates
for India reveal that 20-30 per cent of all babies are born with low
birth weight, suggesting that children begin to get malnourished in
the womb.'' Malnutrition is being transferred from mother to child
as well.
Given such tendencies under capitalism, it has been long accepted
that governments in capitalist societies must intervene to directly
address malnutrition for the social good. Well-fed and healthy children
grow over time into a healthy and productive workforce, which contributes
to national prosperity if they can find jobs. Evidence shows that
government action aimed at reaching food to the poor, can substantially
affect the level of malnutrition, resulting in the observed lack of
correspondence between income levels and the level of malnutrition
across states and countries. Such action would ensure access to food
at affordable prices as well as put purchasing power in the hands
those who are currently deprived of the ability to buy food. What
is best is a combination of: (i) a universally accessible public distribution
system providing essential items at subsidised prices; and (ii) a
public works programme that ensures adequate employment at a reasonable
minimum wage for those not absorbed by the capitalist growth trajectory.
On the surface, the UPA government appears on track to meet these,
having enacted the National Rural Employment Guarantee Act and poised
to enact the Food Security Bill. But in practice, both in terms of
the content of the bills and in terms of implementation on the ground,
there is much to be desired. The NREGA is handicapped by a poor wage
structure that falls short of even the minimum wage mandated in most
states, as well as by inadequate allocations and spending. And the
yet to be enacted Food Security Bill has been so diluted that it is
likely to exclude a substantial section of the needy whose failure
to access adequate food is responsible for the 42 per cent malnutrition
among children.
The reason for this inadequacy in government action is of course liberalisation
and ''economic reform''. Having provided huge direct and indirect
tax concessions to the rich as part of an effort to encourage and
promote private savings and investments, governments at both the centre
and in the states are strapped for funds. In addition, all of them
have been tied down by the philosophy of liberalisation which opposes
deficit spending financed by borrowing. So either deficits are consciously
sought to be reduced (as in the centre) or are kept down by law as
in the states. If tax revenues are not growing adequately and governments
cannot borrow, spending must be curbed. Experience shows that when
expenditures have to be trimmed, it is capital expenditures and expenditures
on social security that are axed. One obvious casualty is spending
on schemes aimed at ensuring food security and rural employment. In
sum, by engineering a fiscal crunch liberalisation militates against
government policies aimed at countering the adverse effects of capitalist
growth on hunger and nutrition. Growth benefits the richest few per
cent at the top, while leaving untouched or even marginalising the
majority.
But that is not all. The other casualty has been a scheme specifically
designed, among other things, to reduce malnutrition among children.
This is the Integrated Child Development Scheme, or ICDS, which was
initiated in October 1975 in response to the evident problems of persistent
hunger and malnutrition especially among children. Among the objectives
of the scheme is that of improving the nutritional and health status
of children in the age group 0-6 years. Since its inception, the ICDS
has grown to become the world's largest early child development programme.
The coverage of the Scheme has expanded rapidly, especially in recent
years. Nevertheless, as is clear from the child malnutrition figures
quoted earlier, for a scheme that has been in operation for three
and a half decades, the benefits are still far too limited.
The basic reason is that not enough resources have been devoted to
this scheme, to meet the huge requirement. Quite simply, there are
not enough anganwadis or anganwadi workers to manage the scheme, and
they do not have adequate resources to meet all the nutritional requirements
of those pregnant and lactating mothers, infants and small children
who need them. The ICDS has been operating on the underpaid labour
of women in an undesirable and unsustainable fashion. While small
increases in wages have been made, it still leaves them receiving
less than minimum wages! Further, the Supreme Court has repeatedly
instructed the government to make the scheme universal to all habitations,
but the small or negligible increase in budgetary allocations to the
ICDS ensures that this will not happen in the near future.
Put simply capitalist growth of the worst variety fostered by neoliberalism
and the consequent refusal of the government to directly address the
problem explains the cause for ''national shame'' that the PM speaks
of. But even if he is finally reading and recognizing the truth that
has been staring everybody in the face, he is unlikely to do very
much about it. Given his conviction, he would, of course, do little
about looking for alternatives to capitalism. What is more, those
same convictions would work against reversing the neoliberal trajectory
he has put the country on since 1991. In the event, he would find
it impossible to put even the shadow of a human face on India's inequalising
growth. The country, therefore, would have to live in shame … till
the UPA and similar governments are replaced by one committed to a
more people-centred development trajectory.