The
coming weeks are to witness two important economic policy announcements.
The first is the next review of monetary policy due at the end of January.
The second is the budget slated for the end of February. These policy
interventions would have to contend with what appears to be a mixed
picture of the state of the economy. The good news is that the Central
Statistical Organisation has put out a reassuring estimate of growth
in the economy, with a better-than-expected recovery in the second quarter
(July-September) of 2009-10. GDP growth that quarter was placed at 7.9
per cent relative to the corresponding quarter of the previous year.
This was not only way beyond growth rates in the previous three quarters
when they averaged between 5.8 and 6.1 per cent, but even marginally
above the growth rates in the first two quarters of 2008-09 when the
effects of the global recession were just beginning to be felt. This
sharp recovery has triggered official speculation that growth in 2009-10
would be 7.5 per cent or more, and that India may even see a quick return
to the 9 per cent growth trajectory of the five years preceding the
slowdown in growth.
The bad news of course is that the overall rate of inflation and especially
the inflation in food prices still continue to climb. Even though inflation
as measured by the Wholesale Price Index is below double-digit levels
(even if climbing), the consumer price index is rising at close to 15
per cent on a month-on-month basis and food price inflation is still
close to 20 per cent. These trends on the growth and inflation fronts
obviously signal that the problem to be immediately addressed is inflation
and not low growth or a recession. Not surprisingly, while one section
of the government argues that it is still too early to withdraw the
fiscal stimulus it claims to have put in place to stall the downturn,
another is increasingly convinced that it is time now to shift attention
to holding down inflation by reining in public and private expenditures.
The government's decision to dampen inflation by augmenting supplies
to the market through increased releases of stocks it holds and larger
imports of commodities like sugar has partly exhausted one of the options
it has at hand. If this effort at supply management does not dampen
the speculation that is clearly responsible for recent increases in
the prices of essential commodities, other measures will have to be
sought. These would involve reducing access to credit and raising interest
rates in the monetary policy that is to come, and limiting deficit-financed
expenditures in the budget for the coming year. Till recently, credit
growth has been sluggish in the economy. In fact, as of January 1, 2010,
the growth in bank credit was placed at 14 per cent for 2009-10, as
compared with the 17.5 per cent recorded in the previous year and the
target of 18 per cent set for the current financial year. But more recently
there appear to be signs of acceleration in credit expansion. According
to figures recently released by the Reserve Bank of India, bank credit
rose by Rs. 79,514.51 crore during the fortnight ending January 1, as
compared with the average credit off-take of Rs. 21,000 crore in the
previous two fortnights. As a result, expectations are that the Reserve
Bank of India may mop up liquidity by hiking the Cash Reserve Ratio
imposed on banks and raising the indicative repo (interest) rate by
anywhere up to half a percentage point.
Similarly, there is no doubt that the budget for 2009-10 would reflect
a large fiscal deficit. So though last minute disinvestment may generate
some receipts for the budget for 2009-10, the level of the fiscal deficit
and the extent of borrowing in that year are bound to be high. This
would only strengthen the case being made by those who want contractionary
policies to deal with inflation.
The impact that moves of this kind would have on growth is likely to
be considerable. A substantial part of the so-called "stimulus"
that is expected to generate the fiscal deficit this year was not engineered
but fortuitous. With the government having had to set up a Pay Commission
for its employees and implement its rather generous recommendations,
which involved paying a large amount as arrears, a substantial increase
in expenditures was inevitable. What has happened is that, because of
the global recession, something that would have otherwise been considered
a "burden" that threatened fiscal stability was in the wake
of the crisis presented as a necessary increase in expenditure in response
to the downturn. If we exclude this unavoidable expenditure, especially
the payment of a large amount as arrears for the period from January
2006, the size of the stimulus adopted specifically in response to the
crisis collapses. Thus, even if the actual stimulus measures, in the
form of tax cuts or increased expenditures, are not withdrawn, central
government expenditure would be curtailed at least to the extent that
once-for-all arrears payments would not feature in next year's allocations.
Since the government has been treating all the increases in its expenditure
(during last and this year) as being a consciously adopted stimulus,
a reduction in the estimated "stimulus" during the next fiscal
is unavoidable. If, in addition, the government chooses to reduce or
even keep constant the actual stimulus launched in response to the downturn
in the form of new expenditures other than its wage and salary bill,
a significant decline in aggregate expenditure that has a countercyclical
influence is the obvious consequence. The question, therefore, is whether
this would leave the recovery untouched without affecting inflation.
An interesting feature of the recovery in GDP growth in the second quarter
of 2009-10 is that, when analysed from the expenditure side, much of
it has been on account of an increase in the government's Final Consumption
Expenditure. This component in the national accounts is the one which
captures the effects of the implementation of the Sixth Pay Commission's
recommendation. Its importance can be gauged from the following: The
sum total of Private Final Consumption Expenditure, Goss Fixed Capital
Formation and Exports which grew at 10.02 and 8.76 per cent respectively
during the first and second quarters of 2008-09, registered changes
of minus 0.51 per cent and a meagre 2.44 per cent in the first and second
quarters of 2009-10. On the other hand, Government Final Consumption
Expenditure which registered changes of 0.19 and 2.19 per cent respectively
in the first and second quarters of 2008-09, grew at a remarkable 10.24
and 26.91 per cent in the first and second quarters of 2009-10. Thus
the recovery was largely the result of an increase in Government Consumption
Expenditure, which would fall both because of the absence of the windfall
Pay Commission arrears payments in the next fiscal and because of any
reduction in the government's stimulus.
Thus, the evidence indicates that, everything else remaining the same,
if the government does not increase its outlays in areas other than
wages and salaries in the next fiscal, we could experience another downturn.
India too seems set for a "double-dip" recession, especially
because the expenditure under the arrears head would not be undertaken
and is unlikely to be substituted with some other set of outlays. In
the circumstances, thinking of dealing with inflation by tightening
monetary policy and exiting from the fiscal stimulus may not be altogether
a good idea.
What is more, there are reasons to believe that an exit from the stimulus
may not be the best way to deal with inflation given its features. To
start with, the inflation in food prices has been with us for some time
now, including during the phase when growth had slowed. That is, it
has been underway even when there has been a contraction in overall
demand. Reducing demand, therefore, does not guarantee a reversal of
the food price increase. Second, while food price inflation has accelerated
after it became clear that rainfall in much of the country during the
southwest monsoon was well below its long-term average, the inflationary
process began before the failed monsoon. So it is not just the expectation
of a decline in supplies that was responsible for the price increase.
Third, the inflation occurs despite the fact that foodgrain stocks with
the government are comfortable, and well above the buffer stocking requirement.
Finally, inflation has occurred even though the country's foreign exchange
reserves are comfortable, giving the government the option of importing
food to augment domestic supplies and rein in prices.
Given all this, the unavoidable conclusion is that food price inflation
is not all the result of inadequate supplies but in substantial measure
the result of speculation. What is called for then is not measures that
work on inflation by reining in growth, but direct measures to deal
with speculators and dishoard their stocks, while augmenting availability
through a strengthened public distribution system. This is likely to
be more effective and less damaging for the economy. But that does not
seem to be the direction the government is taking.