Now
that the economic slowdown is truly upon us, and the government is no
longer in complete denial about the vulnerability of the economy, the
discussion is dominated by the possible effectiveness of the policy
measures that have been announced to deal with it. But this depends
upon two different features: first, what has caused the recession in
the first place; and second, how it will affect different economic agents.
By both counts, the measures announced so far appear to be lacking.
On the first count, there is an official presumption that this is simply
an imported crisis. And there is an associated blindness to important
lessons about the regulation of finance that are coming from the developed
world. Unlike possibly any other government in the world today, the
Indian government is going in for more financial liberalisation, even
when the results of such deregulation in terms of creating unsustainable
bubbles and spawning major crises are there for all to see. While this
may provide some immediate relief by propping up the rupee and stopping
the bleeding of foreign exchange reserves, it will create the conditions
for a much worse country-specific financial crisis in the near future.
On the second count, the policy response thus far is deficient because
it seems to have ignored most of the people who are likely to be badly
affected, in favour of a few who happen to be more well-connected. This
particular economic crisis, because it has both financial and real economic
aspects, is going to affect different people very differently. The financial
sector is clearly hit. Stock market investors have lost (at least nominally)
huge amounts, and the credit crunch is adversely affecting both large
corporates and smaller businesses.
This inevitably has knock-on effects on the real sector, adding reduced
domestic demand to the problem of depressed export markets. And so real
economic activity, in both tradeables and non-tradeables, is affected
and this directly translates into employment losses.
Most of the government’s measures are designed to ease the credit crunch
and revive the stock market and investor confidence: by lowering interest
rates, by propping up the banking system through promises of fresh capitalisation,
by injecting new liquidity through relaxed credit norms. Clearly all
this will not be enough in the current liquidity trap conditions, but
at least it will directly benefit some large banks, corporate houses,
builders and export units. The idea is that this will in turn benefit
those who are employed by such agents, and therefore prevent job losses
that would otherwise occur.
Yet in all this the government is ignoring two major groups of workers
who are already directly hit, and who together account for the majority
of the workers in the country: farmers and migrant labourers. Cultivators
in India have already been through more than a decade of agrarian crisis,
which persisted even through the period of rising international crop
prices. They have then been on a complete roller coaster in price terms
in the past year, as world trade prices of most crops doubled and then
collapsed within a few months, and by the end of the year came to settle
at levels below those of two years ago.
Many cash crop cultivators, who had begun their sowing operations on
the basis of crop prices determined by the relative prices of just a
few months ago, now find that their cultivation will simply be financially
unviable at prevailing input and output prices. With particular regions
of the country, including some of the fragile dry land areas, increasingly
dominated by such cash crop cultivation (such as cotton, groundnuts,
soya beans) it is not difficult to imagine what will happen to livelihoods
in such cases.
This is a major economic catastrophe that is not just waiting to happen
- it is already unfolding. So a series of monetary and fiscal packages
that does not even mention, let alone address, the inevitable problems
of cash crop cultivation, is bizarre to say the least.
The other major group that is already negatively affected is of those
workers who are employed on casual contracts, who now find that even
their fragile jobs no longer exist. Many of these are migrant workers,
often short-term migrants whose very existence tends to be ignored by
our official statistics. The economic boom of the past decade relied
heavily on such workers. This was very obviously true in the construction
industry. But it was also the case in some labour-intensive services,
such as cleaning, maintenance, private security, driving and related
services, that catered to the requirements of the expanding corporate
sector, and in effect subsidised it by providing a cheap and flexible
external labour force. A lot of manufacturing, especially in those sectors
such as garments, leather goods, gems and jewellery and metal products
where exports have been seriously hit by the world recession, have also
increasingly relied on informal contract workers, who could be hired
and fired at will.
Many of these workers have already been laid off and many more will
now indeed be fired, or at any rate lose their jobs at least temporarily.
And so they will be forced either to stay in precarious conditions in
the urban areas, or go back to their places of origin - villages or
smaller towns. They will change from becoming providers of remittance
incomes to their households, to becoming dependents of these households,
even as these households face more fragile material circumstances than
before. And so the negative multiplier effects will permeate geographically.
The potential for social and political upheaval caused by such economic
changes should not be underestimated. The heat will be felt by state
governments, who (despite the paltry provision of more borrowing facility
announced most recently) will also be reeling under the pressure of
coping with reduced tax revenues and increase salary expenditure because
of the recent Pay Commission award. So state governments will not be
in a position to deal with the consequences, unless explicit provision
is made by the Centre for them to cope with these new and adverse circumstances.
This has significant implications, because many of these migrant workers,
for obvious reasons, come from the most depressed and backward regions
of the country, where there is currently little potential for productive
income generation. These are often also the regions of dry land agriculture,
where remittance incomes play a vital role in sheer survival. They are
also - no surprise! - the regions where extremist Maoist activity is
widely prevalent, because of the anger bred by persistent backwardness
and rising inequalities.
So the economic geography of this unfolding crisis is likely to have
huge political fallout. Because we live in an electoral democracy, it
might be expected that the government - or at least the political parties
involved who know they have to face the people in a general election
in just a few months - would take note of these negative effects on
the majority of voters. It is both extraordinary and alarming to realise
that thus far nothing in the policy pronouncements suggests that the
welfare of such people - cultivators and migrant workers - is at all
a consideration for the central government. Their future is being sacrificed
because our rulers seem unable to stop paying homage to a different
type of mobility at the altars of international finance capital, however
discredited this might be in the present global scenario.