It
has been some time since micro-credit was discovered by
the development world. And since then, there has been every conceivable
kind of reaction to it, in a spectrum ranging from euphoria at what
appeared to be the ultimate - and easy - panacea for poverty and lack
of development, to scepticism about its ability to deliver material
betterment, to hostility about a strategy that some have seen as forcing
market relations upon those not fully equipped to handle them.
The
most prominent and well-publicised examples of micro-credit (in terms
of credit to small borrowers without requiring collateral) are of course
in Bangladesh. Institutions like the Grameen Bank and BRAC (the Bangladesh
Rural Advancement Committee) have become the staple celebrities of this
sphere, with their models inspiring other practitioners and even entering
the otherwise esoteric world of theoretical mainstream economics.
Thus,
the group lending scheme pioneered by Grameen (in which the entire group
of borrowers is penalised for the inability of one member to repay,
thereby creating tremendous peer pressure for prompt and full repayment
and reducing the need for hierarchical monitoring) has spawned a spate
of mathematical models designed to illustrate its efficacy. The focus
on lending to women in particular has been admired and emulated not
only because of its role in transforming gender relations, but also
because loan repayment has been found to be more secure in consequence.
But even (or perhaps especially) in Bangladesh, this
model too has its share of detractors, who point out that after more
than two and a half decades of significant lending by such institutions,
there has been no noticeable impact on rural poverty or indeed evidence
of sustainable diversification of rural employment such as to raise
aggregate labour productivity. There are also arguments that the sheer
rigidity of the loan repayment schedule and the small amounts involved
imply that such resources cannot really be used for investment that
contains any degree of risk or requires a longer time frame to fructify,
or for asset building generally. They also do not ameliorate the lot
of the truly destitute, that is those in extreme poverty.
The
most severe critics of this model in fact suggest that because, in Bangladesh
in particular, foreign aid resources have been diverted from the government
budget to such lending institutions, they have meant less expenditure
on public infrastructure and effectively an increase in rural underemployment
rather than open unemployment. Thus, if the macroeconomic tendencies
do not provide more productive employment opportunities, then providing
small amounts of short-term credit can simply lead to a multiplication
of certain service providers, for example, with lower returns for all.
There
is certainly now a more measured view of the effects of such micro-credit
schemes, and a recognition that they are not magical development solutions,
but they can nevertheless be important catalysts for other social and
economic change. And the proliferation of such schemes, especially in
South Asia, has meant that the design of more recent schemes gets modified
in the light of the learning experience of others, which is always to
be welcomed.
These
thoughts are amply illustrated by a set of such schemes currently in
operation in parts of rural Nepal, which show both the advantages of
learning from others and the possibilities of transformation that can
be exploited by such attempts at social mobilisation.
Of
course the context of rural Nepal is quite special, not only because
of the topographical conditions which make even basic communication
and access much more complicated, but because of the political decentralisation
process that has been underway over the past decade. This has already
meant that people have a greater political awareness than earlier. And
even though the economic fallout has been limited, there is evidence
of improved farm productivity because of better infrastructure especially
irrigation and better social indicators such as higher school enrolment
of girls in particular.
But
from there to achieving sufficient confidence enter into major economic
decision-making, even at the local level, or to attempt to control material
destiny, is a large difficult step. This is why an initiative that has
been underway in some districts of central Nepal in recent years is
so significant.
It
began in the district of Syangja in 1994, under the auspices of the
South Asia Poverty Alleviation Programme (SAPAP) of the UNDP, and it
has proved so successful that in the past three years the Government
of Nepal has joined forces with SAPAP to extend the project to other
districts and make it a model for national development. At present,
therefore, the model is being initiated or implemented by 200 Village
Development Councils (VDCs - formerly panchayats, which comprise several
villages) of 45 districts of Nepal.
The
Syangja model is essentially one which tries to combine thrift and credit
schemes and infrastructure development with community participation
in decision making. The role of the external agency is not simply to
provide resources to set up micro-credit activities and undertake rural
infrastructure projects, but even more importantly, to assist in the
development of local organisations which will manage and decide upon
the nature of these activities, and to enhance local skill formation
for this purpose. It is this wider focus which has gives the Syangja
model that extra edge. It has made the programme more relevant in terms
of allowing the local communities more voice in determining service
delivery as well as enhancing the possibilities of genuinely participatory
development planning at the VDC levels as well.
Thus,
in the Syangja model, groups of people (in both mixed and single-sex
groups) form themselves into village or community organisations (VOs),
which then undertake a system of thrift and credit provision. Credit
is both from a revolving fund of received savings and from the VO which
itself borrows from higher tiers. While the initial guidelines may be
suggested by the external agency, basically the decisions about required
savings from all members, amount of loan disbursed, timing of repayment,
and so on, are made by the members of the VO themselves, who also appoint
a Chairperson and a Manager.
In
addition, the VO decides about the implementation of infrastructure
grants which have been provided. A majority of these have gone into
drinking water projects which are sorely needed in the countryside,
and which are already estimated to have reduced the incidence of water-borne
diseases in the relevant areas. Other infrastructure projects have included
irrigation schemes and roads.
The
VOs themselves are then organised into CMCs (Chairperson- Manager Conferences)
which meet once a month, choose their own chair and decide about allocations
across the village organisations. A higher tier is composed of the Local
Trust Fund Board, an elected body with some bureaucratic representations
as well.
All
this may sound like simply the creation of more and more village bureaucrats,
but the reality is rather different. First impressions suggest that
most of the members of the VOs have a great sense of belonging to and
being able to control the decisions of the VO, and view these different
tiers of management as both necessary and important to create a link
with other villages in the area.
The
CMCs in turn become more than simply a formal meeting of the constituent
groups. One such meeting held recently in Keware village was heavily
attended despite the difficulty of crossing hilly terrain to get to
the meeting place. It was also lively and wide ranging in terms of discussions.
The participants thought about new schemes, such as the possibility
of providing livestock insurance, and exchanged notes about important
matters and local and national news. Several people pointed out that
this was an important means, especially in a mountainous area where
communication is otherwise difficult, of getting information and working
out common strategies to deal with problems.
There
are two possible caveats to the currently functioning system. Most decisions
are taken through consensus rather than vote, and this can often be
a problem when power is asymmetrically held. Also, there are still problems
of relative exclusion of the poorest households : while they are typically
members of the VO who make the necessary (and relatively small amount)
of required savings, they usually lack the confidence and repayment
capacity to take loans. For this reason, they typically still remain
dependent upon traditional moneylenders who are more flexible in timing
and often adjust the loan in other ways such as labour services, and
to that extent have been denied the possible benefits of this programme.
Otherwise, however, for most of the rest of the membership, the significance
of traditional moneylenders has declined.
The
material benefits of such a programme - in living standards and changes
in patterns of consumption and savings - are fairly easy to see, even
if they are limited in scope. Thus, in the concerned villages there
has been improvement in some important infrastructure areas, whether
in the form of new roads, better access to drinking water, sanitation
facilities, or irrigation for cultivation. But the real benefits of
this programme are probably less material and more social in nature.
Thus,
the now recognised role of such organisations in terms of empowering
women is evident here as well. Not only do more women participate and
get involved in these activities, but the groups then become vehicles
for broader social mobilisation and consciousness raising. Several women
pointed out how they have gained in confidence, feel more able to participate
actively in public life, and may choose to benefit from various kinds
of training. The process of creating, being involved in and running
these organisations also requires various kinds of skill, not just bookkeeping
but other skills, which are made evident and then developed by the programme.
increasingly, the VOs have been showing initiative in asking for or
organising training programmes that provide for skills that are felt
to be in short supply, whether in animal husbandry or in agriculture
or in other manufacturing and service activities.
One
of the most important effects is probably in terms of the effects on
the VO members in terms of increasing their capacity to respond and
participate as citizens. Thus, not only is there greater recognition
of the advantages within a village, of working together and co-operation,
but the relationship with other public and private agents outside the
village also becomes more active and informed. thus, some awareness
of the issues involved in building local infrastructure allows for a
more reasoned assessment of public activities in this regard, and also
builds more community participation in assessing other economic activities
of the state and other big players in the area.
This
is a feature which is a fundamental requirement of true democracy, and
any institutions which act as catalysts to enable people to demand more
control over various aspects of their own quotidian life are therefore
of great importance. This is why the significance of programmes such
as this one in Nepal go well beyond the specific effects of certain
loans, and extend into the conditions for ensuring more enduring democratic
participation in economic decision-making. Surely there is an important
lesson in this for the rest of South Asia.
|