The
declaration by the government-owned conglomerate Dubai World that
it proposes to unilaterally suspend payments due on its large debt
has triggered a new fear in international financial circles: that
of sovereign default. Strictly speaking, the sums owed by Dubai World
were not sovereign debts, but debts incurred by the company. But because
of the nature of the company's ownership, these debts were seen as
(implicitly) guaranteed by the Dubai government. Since Dubai is part
of the United Arab Emirates, these debts were also seen as being implicitly
guaranteed by the leading nation in the group, the oil-rich Abu Dhabi.
Given these features, the message sent out by the Dubai World declaration
that it plans to suspend and reschedule its debt service obligations
was that in today's world nothing is secure. Other governments too
can choose to default in order to reschedule excessive debt involving
cumbersome payments requirements, buying time today and leaving it
to future parties in power to deal with the consequences. This possibility
flagged in by Dubai together with the changed distribution of sovereign
debt globally has created a peculiar situation: it is not governments
of poor developing countries with limited resources and limited possibilities
of transformation through trade of local into foreign currencies that
are now the principal source of danger, but more developed countries
like Greece, Italy, the US and the United Kingdom.
Governments have always taken on debt: to finance wars, investments
and day-to-day expenditures. Besides borrowing themselves they have
also implicitly or explicitly guaranteed private debt, to facilitate
borrowing by non-government entities. Put these together, and some
of them had at different points in time borrowed ''excessively'',
in the sense that they had accumulated debt service commitments that
were too heavy a burden given their willingness or ability to mobilise
domestic resources to defray such expenditures. Governments of poorer
countries were also victims of the so-called ''original sin'' or the
inability to borrow abroad (or even at home) in the domestic currency.
This meant that they needed to transform domestic resources into adequate
amounts of foreign currency to meet debt service obligations denominated
in terms of a foreign currency.
Inevitably, therefore, there were two contradictory aspects to sovereign
debt, or debt owed by a national government. The first is that such
debt was considered to be much safer than other forms of debt since
it had the backing of a national government that could (normally)
commandeer the resources needed to meet payments commitments. The
other is that such debt is not all too safe, since unlike in the cases
of individuals and firms, creditors most often cannot force governments
to repay debt by taking them to the courts and having their assets
liquidated. Rather, sovereign debts are potential candidates for compulsory
rescheduling in terms of payment periods, interest rates and valuation
or even candidates for full repudiation.
Repudiation or even compulsory rescheduling is not without costs.
It affects the reputation of the country and government concerned,
triggers a sharp reduction in the rating of its foreign debt and damages
the ability of the country to access further debt. It could lead to
the imposition of trade sanctions against the country by governments
of countries from which its principal creditors originate. And these
and other reputational effects can have political costs for the governments
and parties that opt for such repudiation. It is the existence of
such costs that are seen as ensuring that creditors do lend to governments.
The reality, of course, is that defaults have indeed occurred. In
the past, these have been defaults by developing countries. According
to one analysis (Borensztein & Panizza, 2008) relating to the
period 1824-2004: ''Latin America is the region with the highest number
of default episodes at 126, Africa, with 63 episodes, is a distant
second. The Latin American ''lead'' is, however, largely determined
by the fact that Latin American countries gained independence and
access to international financial markets early in the 19th century,
while most African countries continued to be European colonies for
another 100 or 150 years. Among the developing regions, Asia shows
the lowest number of defaults.''
Most often defaults in developing countries occur when they have been
the targets of a lending boom. One such boom preceded the debt crisis
in Latin America in the early 1980s. Net resource flows from private
creditors rose sharply in the 1970s, driven from the supply side by
the huge inflows of deposits into the international banking system
after the oil shocks of the 1970s. According to Jonathan Eaton and
Raquel Fernandez (1995), for debtors classified by the World Bank
as ''severely indebted countries'', such flows peaked at nearly 2
per cent of their GNP in 1976. After the Mexican debt crisis of 1982,
the direction of these flows was reversed, peaking at over 2 per cent
in 1986. Sovereign debt for the group amounted to 30 per cent of GDP
in 1986, partly because the rescheduling process involved provision
of additional loans to prevent default.
The implication of that experience is that in the case of developing
countries, the tendency to default is the result of them having been
given and having accepted external debt that becomes difficult to
pay either because they are subject to some shock or because the magnitude
is just too large. Often a lot of this debt is not even sovereign
debt but debt to the domestic private sector, provided in the belief
that there is an implicit sovereign guarantee. Yet, repudiation is
not necessarily an answer to the problem, since it could lead to reduced
access to foreign exchange that is crucial to sustain domestic investment
and even consumption. Developing country governments, therefore, accept
onerous rescheduling terms (in recent years under IMF tutelage), which
saves the creditor from having to write down those loans while condemning
the debtor country to low growth and increased deprivation.
Having been the victims of such experiences over the last two decades
of the last century, governments in many (though not all) developing
countries have been cautious about taking on too much debt. This was
a problem for finance since over the last decade the international
financial system has once again been awash with liquidity. This has
resulted in two tendencies: first, increased lending to the private
sector in developing and developed countries; and, second, increased
lending to developed country governments. The latter is the source
of fear in the post-Dubai World period. According to The Economist
(3 December 2009): ''In 2007 average government debt in the G20's
big rich economies, at just under 80% of GDP, was double that of big
emerging economies. By 2014 the ratio, at 120% of GDP, could be more
than three times higher. That alone will challenge old rules of thumb
about the relative riskiness of emerging-market debt. But it will
not be the only change. The scale of contingent liabilities, such
as government guarantees on bank debt, differs hugely between countries,
with a far bigger increase in the rich economies at the heart of the
crisis.''
The problem has been exacerbated by the effort made by a number of
countries to save their banks by buying out their losses and stimulating
the economy with additional spending. This has not just left the debt
overhang problem untouched, it has aggravated it. Needless to say,
the debt is now substantially government or sovereign debt. But increase
in such debt is undermining the confidence that such debt is risk-free,
especially when fiscal deficits, exceed 10 per cent or more of GDP
as they do in Ireland, Greece and Spain.
One economy in the eurozone which is the focus of attention is Greece.
With a budget deficit that is expected to touch at least 12.7 per
cent of GDP, Greece is seen as a country on track to record a public
debt to GDP ratio of 135 per cent. A substantial part of the country
debt is owed to foreign creditors, with two-thirds of public debt
held by foreigners and gross external debt, private and public, estimated
at 149.2 per cent of GDP last year. According to reports, Deutsche
Bank has estimated that Greece would seek to raise some €31 billion
in new borrowing and roll over €16 billion of past debt in the coming
year. This suggests that the country is an ideal candidate for sovereign
default. Greece is not the only potential defaulter. Italy's debt
to GDP ratio is forecast to rise to 127 per cent next year.
Until recently these figures, which point to the potential for default,
were ignored, because stronger economies in the eurozone (like Germany)
were expected to bail out partner countries in the event of a crisis.
But that is unlikely to happen because of the moral hazard involved.
If countries have violated the spirit and letter of the eurozone treaty
to get themselves into this difficult situation, rescuing them would
only encourage them and others to continue with such practices. In
the event, uncertainty builds and investors are paying much money
to insure themselves against sovereign defaults. According to the
Financial Times, ''the volume of activity in sovereign credit default
swaps--which measure the cost to insure against bond defaults--linked
to the US, UK and Japan have doubled in the past year due to concerns
about their public finances.'' This is indeed a whole new context
in which problems that were considered typical of the so-called emerging
markets now plague the metropolitan centres of capitalism. In response,
capital is fleeing to safety in emerging markets, leading to stock
and property market booms and an appreciation of their currencies--all
of which increase fragility in those markets as well.
Borensztein,
E., & U. Panizza (2008) The Costs of Sovereign Default, International
Monetary Fund, Research Department, Washington, D.C.: International
Monetary Fund.
Eaton, J., & R. Fernandez (1995) Sovereign Debt, Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
* This article first appeared as the H.T. Parekh
Finance column in the EPW dated December 12-18, 2008.