Many
people, especially in India, tend to believe that the process of economic
growth is likely to be mostly liberating for those oppressed by various
forms of social discrimination and exclusion. The argument is that
market forces break open age-old social norms, especially those of
caste and gender, that have for so long denied opportunities and restricted
options for so many.
Unfortunately,
the current Indian reality is more complex than that. The strength
of Indian large capital, which is leading the current economic boom,
derives at least partly from the persistence and even expansion of
a wide range of workers engaged in precarious and low-productivity
employment. Most significantly from the point of view of the Indian
corporate sector, different degrees of outsourcing have blurred the
lines between formal and informal activities, and the proliferation
of such low-paying self-employment has become an important means of
reducing costs for the corporate sector as well passing on the risks
of production to smaller units that are essentially part of the working
class.
The extent to which all successful formal economic activities in India
rely on the implicit subsidies provided by cheap informal labour is
largely unrecognised. Yet corporate profitability in India hinges
substantially on the lowering of a wide range of fixed costs through
outsourcing. Thus, for example, the success of the much-lauded software
industry in India is only partly because of cheaper skilled IT professionals
compared to their international counterparts. A significant part of
the lower costs comes from the entire range of support services: cleaning
and maintenance of offices, transport, security, back office work,
catering, and so on. These are usually outsourced to smaller companies
that hire temporary workers with much lower wages, no job security,
very long hours of work and hardly any form of worker protection or
other benefits. Without the cost advantages indirectly conferred by
these low paid workers, the domestic software industry would find
it much harder to compete internationally. The same is true of a wide
range of corporate activities across both manufacturing and the newer
services.
These processes of direct and indirect underwriting of the costs of
the corporate sector have been greatly assisted by the ability of
employers in India to utilise social characteristics to ensure lower
wages to certain categories of workers. Caste and other forms of social
discrimination have a long tradition in India, and they have interacted
with capitalist accumulation to generate peculiar forms of labour
market segmentation that are probably unique to Indian society. Numerous
studies have found that social categories are strongly correlated
with the incidence of poverty and that both occupation and wages differ
dramatically across social categories. The National Sample Surveys
reveal that the probability of being in a low wage occupation is significantly
higher for STs, SCs, Muslims and OBCs (in that order) compared to
the general ''caste Hindu'' population. This is only partly because
of differences in education and level of skill, which are also important
and which in turn reflect the differential provision of education
across social categories.
Such caste-based discrimination has operated in both urban and rural
labour markets. For example, even in a major metropolitan area like
Delhi which is one of the epicentres of economic expansion, there
continues to significant discrimination against Dalit workers operating
dominantly through the mechanism of assignment to jobs, with Dalits
largely entering poorly-paid ''dead-end'' jobs. These are actually
essential jobs in both production, such as sweepers, loaders, unskilled
construction workers, and services, such as shop and sales assistants
and security guards and the like. Methods of recruitment based on
contacts, which are widely prevalent in such low-skilled occupations,
cause past discrimination to carry over to the present and thereby
condemn lower caste groups to providing poorly remunerated labour
that is nonetheless essential to income generation in the economy
as a whole.
Similarly, empirical studies of caste behaviour in rural India have
found that there are many ways in which caste practices operate to
reduce the access of the lower castes to local resources as well as
to income earning opportunities, thereby forcing them to provide their
labour at the cheapest possible rates to employers. One study (Ghanshyam
Shah, Harsh Mander, Sukhdeo Thorat, Satish Deshpande and Amita Baviskar,
''Untouchability in Rural India'', New Delhi: Sage Publications, 2006)
of various caste-based practices in rural areas of 11 states (Punjab,
Uttar Pradesh, Bihar, Madhya Pradesh including Chhattisgarh, Rajasthan,
Maharashtra, Orissa, Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, Kerala and Tamil Nadu)
found, in addition to the well-known lack of assets, a large number
of social practices that effectively restricted the economic activity
of lower caste and Dalit groups, and forced them to supply very low
wage labour in harsh and usually precarious conditions.
In 73 per cent of the villages surveyed in this study, Dalits could
not enter non-Dalit homes. In 70 per cent of villages, Dalits could
not eat with non-Dalits. In 64 per cent of villages, Dalits could
not enter common temples. In 36 per cent of survey villages, Dalits
could not enter village shops. In around one-third of the survey villages,
Dalits were not accepted as traders dealing with commonly used items
of consumption or production. These practices in turn can be used
to keep wages of Dalit workers (who are extremely constrained in their
choice of occupation) low, even in period of otherwise rising wages.
And these practices persist even during the period of the Indian economy's
much-vaunted dynamic growth.
But the important point to note here is not simply that such practices
continue to exist, but that they have become the base on which the
economic accumulation process rests. In other words, capitalism in
India, especially in its most recent globally integrated variant,
has used past and current modes of social discrimination and exclusion
to its own benefit, to facilitate the extraction of surplus and ensure
greater flexibility and bargaining to employers when dealing with
workers. So social categories are not ''independent'' of the accumulation
process – rather, they allow for more surplus extraction, because
they reinforce low employment generating (and therefore persistently
low wage) tendencies of growth.
Similar tendencies are evident in patterns of gender discrimination
as well. With respect to women's work, there have been four apparently
contradictory trends: simultaneous increases in the incidence of paid
labour, underpaid labour, unpaid labour, and the open unemployment
of women. This is a paradox, since it is generally expected that when
employment increases, then unemployment comes down; or when paid labour
increases, then unpaid labour decreases.
For urban women, the increase in regular work has dominantly been
in services, including most importantly the relatively low-paid and
less desirable activity of domestic service, along with some manufacturing.
In manufacturing, there has been some recent growth of petty home-based
activities of women, typically with very low remuneration, performing
outsourced as part of a larger production chain. But explicitly export-oriented
employment, even in special zones set up for the purpose, still accounts
for only a tiny fraction of women's paid work in urban India. Meanwhile,
in rural India self-employment has come to dominate women's activities
even in non-agricultural occupations, largely because of the evident
difficulty of finding paid work.
In this period of economic boom, average real wages of women workers
increased relatively little over the ten year period 1993-94 to 2004-05
despite rapid increases in national income over this period, and for
some categories of women workers (rural graduates and urban illiterate
females) real wages actually declined. What is more, there were fairly
sharp increases in gender gaps in wages, are now among the highest
in the world.
Even public services rely heavily on the underpaid labour of women.
While a privileged minority of women in government employment continue
to access the benefits of the government behaving as a ''model employer'',
new employment for the purpose of providing essential public services
has been concentrated in low-remuneration activities with uncertain
contracts and hardly any benefits. This is true of school education
(with the employment of para-teachers) as well as health and nutrition
(with reliance on anganwadi workers and ASHAs).
The Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme is the
only public intervention to make some difference in this, with evidence
of gender gaps in rural wage work coming as a result of the implementation
of the scheme.
Conditions of self-employment among women show many of the disturbing
tendencies of wage employment. Women's self-employment in non-agriculture
is largely characterised by both low expectations regarding incomes
and remuneration and substantial non-fulfilment of even these low
expectations. Despite some increase in high-remuneration self-employment
among professionals and micro-entrepreneurs, in general the expansion
of self-employment seems to be a distress-driven process, determined
by the lack of availability of sufficient paid work on acceptable
terms. Case studies and evidence from large surveys of the NSS both
suggest that payment for home-based work, which is typically on piece
rates and accounts for increasing proportions of the economic activity
of women, have been declining not only in real but even in nominal
terms in many urban centres, despite the economic dynamism of the
areas in general.
Similarly, unpaid labour of women is likely to have been increasing
because of public policies such as reduced social expenditure that
place a larger burden of care on women, or privatised or degraded
common property resources or inadequate infrastructure facilities
that increase time spent on provisioning essential goods for the household,
or simply because even well-meaning policies (such as for afforestation)
are often gender-blind.
Once
again, the relevant point here is not simply that such gender differences
exist, but that they – and therefore the particular forms that patriarchy
takes in India - are closely intertwined with processes of capitalist
accumulation. So the recent growth has not broken existing pattern
of social discrimination, instead it has relied on them to take forward
the growth story.