It
perhaps is a little too early to predict the coming death of "neoliberalism",
or the economic philosophy that governments should facilitate the functioning
of "free" economic agents rather than regulate them. More crudely
put, the idea is that markets should be left free to work so long as they
deliver profits. But globally evidence has been growing that markets are
just not working, precipitating crises that requires bringing the state
back in. Oil prices have risen to levels close to their inflation-adjusted
historic highs and there are no signs of quick adjustment. Governments,
therefore, need to ensure that prices in the areas they govern are not
left to the market. Financial markets that had convinced some policy makers
of their ability to govern themselves are facing their worst crisis. The
sub-prime problem, everybody admits, is merely a symptom of a deeper malaise
which calls for a return to intensive regulation. And the crisis in global
food markets, that has triggered food riots which threaten to spread globally,
has made clear that nations cannot expect markets to deliver crucial public
goods like food security.
These, however, are the starkest and most critical failures of neoliberal
policy. But there have for some time now been many areas where outcomes
that were initially considered signs of the success of neoliberalism have
turned out to be more of a problem that an economic gain. In the Indian
case, consider, for example, the increase in foreign exchange reserves
because of a more liberal policy with regard to foreign direct and portfolio
investment and foreign borrowing. During the 1990s the resulting accumulation
of reserves, though gradual, was quoted as evidence of the success of
neoliberal policy. In 1991, India had faced a foreign exchange crisis.
The change in policy that followed, it is argued, ensured that we have
enough and more reserves to prevent the recurrence of any such crisis.
More recently, however, the perspective on reserves has changed. The problem
now is that we have too much. Foreign currency assets accumulated by the
Reserve Bank of India crossed the $300 billion mark in early April, having
risen by more than $100 billion over the previous year. Much has been
written about the difficulties this rapid accumulation creates for the
central bank in terms of both exchange rate and monetary management. Rising
reserves have as their counterpart increases in money supply, which the
RBI wants to rein in given the inflationary conditions prevailing in the
economy. But, large and persistent inflows of foreign currency imply that
unless the RBI mops up these dollars through its purchases, the rupee
would appreciate with adverse consequences for India’s already beleaguered
exporters. In practice, the RBI has intervened substantially in forex
markets, even if it has not been completely successful in stalling rupee
appreciation.
Caught in this quandary, the RBI and, more recently, the government, have
been contemplating the possibility of limiting inflows. But the efficacy
of any measures adopted towards that end would depend on the kind of inflows
that predominantly account for such accumulation. Detailed figures on
the sources of accretion of foreign exchange reserves over the period
April to December 2007 (Table 1), recently released by the RBI, permit
an assessment of the room for manoeuvre the government has to adopt policies
that can realise its goals. The figures show that, after allowing for
valuation changes, foreign currency reserves with the RBI rose by $76.1
billion between the beginning of April and the end of December of 2007.
Table
1: Sources of Accretion to Foreign Exchange Reserves |
|
April-December
2007 |
April-December
2006 |
Current
Account Balance |
-16 |
-14 |
Capital
Account (net) (a to f) |
83.2 |
30.2 |
Foreign
Investment (i+ii) |
41.4 |
12.8 |
(i)
Foreign Direct Investment |
8.4 |
7.6 |
(ii) Portfolio Investment |
33 |
5.2 |
Banking
Capital |
5.8 |
0.2 |
of
which: NRI Deposits |
-0.9 |
3.7 |
Short-Term
Credit |
10.8 |
5.7 |
External
Assistance |
1.3 |
1 |
External
Commercial Borrowings |
16.3 |
9.8 |
Other
items in capital account |
7.6 |
0.7 |
Valuation
change |
8.9 |
9.4 |
Total
(I+II+III) |
76.1 |
27.8 |
Source:
Reserve Bank of India. |
Among the factors underlying this rise in reserves, are invisible receipts
that helped cover a substantial share of the deficit on the merchandise
trade account recorded during April to December 2007. According to balance
of payments figures from the RBI, gross invisibles receipts comprising
current transfers (that include remittances from Indians overseas), revenues
from services exports, and income amounted to $100.2 billion during April
to December of 2007. The increase in invisibles receipts was mainly led
by remittances from overseas Indians ($13.8 billion) and software services
($27.5 billion). After accounting for outflows net invisible receipts
stood at $50.5 billion.
The result of these inflows was that while on a BoP basis the merchandise
trade deficit had increased from $50.3 billion during April to December
2006 to $66.5 billion during April to December 2007, or by more than $16
billion, the current account deficit had gone up by just $2 billion from
$14 billion to $16 billion.
Given its small size, financing that deficit with capital inflows was
not a problem. The problem in fact has turned out to be exactly the opposite:
capital inflows have been too large. Net capital inflows during the first
nine months of financial year 2007-08 amounted to $83.2 billion. The three
major items accounting for these inflows were portfolio investments ($33
billion), external commercial borrowings ($16.3 billion) and short term
credit ($10.8 billion). To accommodate these and other flows of smaller
magnitude, without resulting in a substantial appreciation of the rupee,
the central bank had to purchase dollars and increase its s reserve holdings
(after adjusting for valuation changes) by as much as $76 billion or by
an average of around $8.5 billion every month. This trend has only intensified
since then with reserves having risen by $33.8 billion between the end
of December 2007 and the end of Mach 2008 or by an average of more than
$11 billion a month.
Though inflation is now the focus of policy attention in the country,
the government cannot postpone any further dealing with this problem.
The first step the government needs to take is to put a stop to borrowing
abroad by Indian corporates, much of which is to finance rupee expenditures.
This is a clear form of a carry trade in which loans at lower than domestic
interest rates in foreign markets is used to finance domestic investments,
some of which may even be speculative, in the hope that the investor concerned
can not merely benefit from differentials in the rates of return but also
from the appreciation of the rupee between the time the loan is contracted
and repaid. There is no reason why the government and the central bank
should be left with a macroeconomic muddle just because sections of the
private sector are looking for quick returns. A return to a more stringent
external borrowing regime with lower ceilings is the obvious option for
the government.
Controlling the second of the flows that are resulting in large accretion
of foreign exchange reserves, namely, portfolio investment flows is more
difficult. This consists of flows in which the acquisition of shares by
a single foreign investor in an Indian company is less than 10 per cent
of the aggregate shareholding. This could occur either through the FII
route involving purchases of shares in the stock market or the private
placement route where share acquisition is ensured through negotiations
with the promoters. Acquisitions through private placements now far exceed
acquisitions through the stock market. Thus, while the SEBI reports that
net FII inflows in the form of equity and debt during April to December
2007 was around $18 billion (Chart 1), the RBI reports that net portfolio
investment during the period was $33 billion. Almost as much portfolio
investment seems to be coming through the private placement route as is
happening through the FII route.
This suits foreign investors, investments by whom would otherwise have
been constrained by the volume of free floating shares of listed companies
that are available for trading. This is known to be small. Private placements
suit Indian promoters as well because they are in a position to sell,
at a premium, a small slice of shares, which would not threaten their
control over the company. If these are new shares issued for the purpose
and if the premium is large enough, the company obtains a relatively large
volume of resources to finance expansion. In return for this investment
existing shareholders who now own a part of a larger company need to reward
the foreign investors with dividends only when profits are made. If the
promoters had resorted to borrowing instead, interest and amortisation
payments would have to be paid irrespective of the profit performance
of the company. It is of course true that foreign investors are resorting
to such investments in the hope of selling out these shares at a later
date at an appreciated price. If such expectations are realised, the promoters
gains because it increases the market valuation of their own shares and
therefore their net worth. If these expectations are not realised the
promoters anyway benefit from the expansion of the company financed with
funds obtained at extremely low cost. Here again, it is the search for
significant gains by domestic wealthholders that is partly driving the
large inflow.
|