If the
financial media are to be believed, the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) is rethinking its views on
liberalisation of financial markets in developing
countries. For more than two decades now the IMF has been
the world's leading and most successful advocate of
liberalisation of financial markets in both developed and
developing countries. There was, however, a difference in
the role of the IMF in the so-called "mature" and
"emerging" markets. Financial liberalisation in the
developed countries was an internal and autonomous process
driven by the rise to dominance of finance capital. The
IMF merely adopted that programme based on its discovery
of the "value" of that regime.
The earnestness with which it subsequently pursued its
new-found mission to open up financial markets in
developing countries led to criticism that Wall Street,
more than even the U.S. Treasury, was influencing the
stance of the IMF. This changed focus from an emphasis on
trade liberalisation accompanied with policies aimed at
balance of payments adjustment to an emphasis on financial
market policies served the IMF well, since it provided the
Fund with a new role in a world of predominantly private
capital flows. The subsequent success of the IMF in
ensuring financial liberalisation in developing countries
was reflective of the new clout it had garnered as a
formally unnamed representative of international finance.
It is surprising, therefore, that in recent months there
have seen a spate of analyses from the IMF attempting to
revisit the experience with financial liberalisation
worldwide and assess the gains and losses from the wave of
liberalisation in developed and developing country
financial markets over the last decade. This desire to
revisit the debate on financial liberalisation has been
attributed to two factors. First, evidence that the
viability of the Anglo-Saxon, particularly U.S., model of
financial markets and financial policies, is itself in
question. According to the Global Financial Stability
Report released by the Fund in March this year, between
the stock market peak recorded on March 24, 2000 and the
end of February 2003, the S&P 500 stock market index had
fallen by 45 per cent, the NASDAQ by 73 per cent and the
FTSE Eurotop 300 by 55 per cent. This was the period,
which not merely witnessed the bursting of the new
technology bubble but also a further decline encouraged by
evidence of accounting frauds and market manipulation. The
resultant huge erosion of paper wealth has raised
questions about the appropriateness of organisational
forms in U.S. financial markets.
More damaging has been the evidence that the last decade
and a half, when the wave of financial liberalisation in
developing countries was unleashed, has witnessed a series
of financial and currency crises, the intensity of some of
which has been severe. Moreover, analyses of individual
instances of crises have tended to conclude that the
nature and timing of these crises had much to do with the
shift to a more liberal and open financial regime. The
latest set of countries affected by the volatility
described by the IMF as the "feast or famine" dynamic is
in Latin America, where Argentina and Brazil, two
relatively good performers until quite recently, have been
hit by reduced or near negligible access to capital
markets. These instances of volatility followed a spate of
crises in developing country markets in Asia, Africa,
Europe and Latin America during the 1980s and 1990s. Yet
there were no signs of any rethink on the effects of
financial liberalisation, and the prevailing global
financial architecture was defended by the Bretton Woods
institutions on the grounds that it had served the
objective of economic growth well and required, if
anything, minor modifications accompanied by supportive
institutional strengthening.
However, there are superficial signs of a change in
attitude more recently. An IMF working paper, authored by
Graciela Kaminsky of George Washington University and
Sergio Schmukler of the World Bank, authorised for
distribution in February 2003 by the IMF's Chief Economist
and Research Director Kenneth Rogoff, declares that
findings in the "crisis literature" suggest that "booms
and busts in financial markets are at the core of currency
crises and that these large cycles are triggered by
financial deregulation", even though some of "the finance
literature tends to support the claim that deregulation is
beneficial, with liberalisation reducing the cost of
capital".
More recently, an IMF study dated March 17, 2003 and
titled "Effects of Financial Globalisation on Developing
Countries: Some Empirical Evidence", which includes
Kenneth Rogoff among its co-authors, has gone even
further. It recognises: (i) that "an objective reading of
the vast research effort to date suggests that there is no
strong, robust and uniform support for the (neo-liberal)
theoretical argument that financial globalisation per
se delivers a higher rate of economic growth; and (ii)
that even though neo-liberal theory suggests that "the
volatility of consumption relative to that of output
should go down as the degree of financial integration
increases, since the essence of global financial
diversification is that a country is able to offload some
of its income risk in world markets," in practice "the
volatility of consumption growth relative to that of
income growth has on average increased for the emerging
market economies in the 1990s, which was precisely the
period of a rapid increase in financial globalisation."
This new candour on the part of the IMF has not gone
unnoticed. The Financial Times declared that "the
new study marks a continued shift within the IMF towards
much greater caution in encouraging countries to open up
their capital accounts," necessitated in particular by its
experience in Argentina and Brazil. Another observer
remarked: "The IMF has just abandoned its fatwa
against the unmitigated evil of capital controls.
Institutional confessions of error do not come much bigger
than this one. But while the IMF's many critics are
rubbing it in, they should not forget that such a burst of
intellectual honesty takes a lot of guts."
The reality regarding the IMF's attitude is, however,
entirely different. A close reading of both the working
paper and the study referred to earlier indicates that the
IMF has decided to accommodate the growing evidence of the
adverse consequences of financial liberalisation in
developing countries not so much to learn from it and
revise its positions but to provide what some are seeing
as a more "nuanced" defence of financial liberalisation.
In fact, Kaminsky and Schmukler argue that the problem
with existing analyses of financial liberalisation is that
they separate countries into those that have and those
that have not liberalised their financial markets. In
actual fact, countries remove different kinds of
restrictions at different times, which not merely lead to
different degrees and patterns of financial liberalisation
but also to "reversal" of the liberalisation trend in many
contexts.
Once these features of the extent of liberalisation of
individual markets are considered, they argue, the
evidence suggests that stock market booms and busts have
not intensified in the long run after financial
liberalisation. The real difference between developed and
developing countries is that in the latter the evidence
indicates that in the short run financial liberalisation
tends to trigger larger cycles, even though it is
beneficial in the long run. In comparison, liberalisation
in mature markets appears to be beneficial in the short
run as well.
What explains this difference in the case of the
developing countries? It is, according to the authors, the
fact that institutional reforms aimed at increasing
transparency and appropriate regulation of markets do not
predate liberalisation. It is only after liberalisation is
adopted as a strategy that governments turn their
attention to institutional quality, resulting in the fact
that the institutional requirements, needed to ensure that
liberalisation delivers its beneficial effects, are put in
place only with a lag. This leads to the paradoxical
contrast between the short-run adverse and long-run
beneficial effects of financial liberalisation.
The IMF's own study builds on this argument, indicating
that the timing and sequence of the release of the two
analyses may not be coincidental. Taking a more nuanced
view of liberalisation, as the Kaminsky-Schmukler paper
does, the IMF study divides countries into those that are
more and less financially liberalised not on the basis of
their de jure liberalisation suggested by their
policies, but on the basis of their de facto
liberalisation as indicated by the volume of capital
inflows and outflows relative to GDP. Thus, if a country
has not adopted liberalisation measures to any significant
degree but has received large capital inflows, it is
treated as a more liberalised financial market. That is,
the link between liberalisation and capital flows is
assumed and not established.
Having classified countries in this manner, the study
finds that there is no clearly identifiable effect of
financial liberalisation on growth in developing countries
and that there is evidence that consumption volatility, in
fact, increases with liberalisation. However, the study
goes on to argue: "Interestingly, a more nuanced look at
the data suggests the possible presence of a threshold
effect. At low levels of financial integration, an
increment in financial integration is associated with an
increase in the relative volatility of consumption.
However, once the level of financial integration crosses a
threshold, the association becomes negative. In other
words, for countries that are sufficiently open
financially, relative consumption volatility starts to
decline. This finding is potentially consistent with the
view that international financial integration can help to
promote domestic financial sector development, which in
turn can help to moderate domestic macroeconomic
volatility."
This makes the proliferation of financial and currency
crises among developing economies a natural consequence of
the "growing pains" associated with financial
globalisation, and therefore an inevitable stage they have
to go through to realise the gains of liberalisation. But
what causes these short-term crises? The IMF study itself
identifies four factors. First, international investors
have a tendency to engage in momentum trading and herding,
which can be destabilising. Second, international
investors "may" engage in speculative attacks on
developing country currencies, leading to instability that
is not warranted by fundamentals. Third, the "contagion"
effect, which has been repeatedly observed, could result
in international investors withdrawing capital from
otherwise healthy countries. Finally, some governments may
not give sufficient weight to the interest of future
generations and exploit financial globalisation to
over-borrow with purely short-term considerations in mind.
Needless to say, all of these, have a mutually reinforcing
effect that exacerbates financial crises when they occur.
It should be obvious that of these, the first three have
little to do with the behaviour of developing country
governments or financial agents but with the behaviour of
financial agents from developed countries. Since
developing countries can do little about the latter, the
case for pre-empting the effects of such behaviour with
financial controls is strong. Yet, having recognised their
importance the IMF study goes on to argue: "The
vulnerability of a developing country to the `risk
factors' associated with financial globalisation is also
not independent from the quality of macroeconomic policies
and domestic governance. For example, research has
demonstrated that an overvalued exchange rate and an
overextended domestic lending boom often precede a
currency crisis. In addition, lack of transparency has
been shown to be associated with more herding behaviour by
international investors that can destabilise a developing
country's financial markets. Finally, evidence shows that
a high degree of corruption may affect the composition of
a country's capital inflows in a manner that makes it more
vulnerable to the risks of speculative attacks and
contagion effects."
Developed industrial countries, the study implicitly
suggests, do not have these institutional features that
generate the vicious nexus between financial
liberalisation and short-term volatility leading to
periodic crises. To be like the developed, developing
countries have to cross the "threshold", since the greater
financial integration that this requires would
automatically lead to improvements in institutional
quality as well. So the implication is not that developing
countries should give up on financial liberalisation but
that they should go far enough to ensure that it is
accompanied with reform that delivers the institutional
quality needed to realise the virtuous relationship
between financial liberalisation and economic performance.
This is indeed surprising, given the evidence of the
factors that led up to the collapse of stock markets in
the developed countries, especially in the U.S. As
mentioned earlier, that collapse was exacerbated by
evidence of conflict of interest (as in the Merrill Lynch
case), of market manipulation (Enron) and of accounting
fraud (Enron, WorldCom, Xerox), which does not say much
either for the transparency or quality of institutions in
the U.S. If it was institutional quality that accounts for
the threshold effect, if any such exists, then the
instances of successful and failed financial
liberalisation should not coincide with their
categorisation as "mature" or "emerging markets".
The failure of the studies quoted to take account of these
factors points in two directions. First, it suggests that
the effort to make a more "nuanced" classification of
countries into those that are more and less liberalised
amounts to manipulating the evidence to yield results that
defend liberalisation in the long term, even though its
consequences are obviously adverse. Second, the new
candour is not a reflection of the need to change track
but of the need to ensure that liberalisation is persisted
with despite the ostensibly short-run "pains" of the
process. The IMF's case is clear-it does not deny the
volatility, the crises and the pain associated with
financial liberalisation; it merely sees them as the
inevitable consequence that must be suffered to enjoy the
long-run benefits of liberalisation. The strategy is to
assert that evidence that contradicts its case is actually
supportive.
|