If the
financial media are to be believed, the International Monetary Fund (IMF)
is rethinking its views on liberalization of financial markets in
developing countries. For more than two decades now the IMF has been the
world's leading and most successful advocate of liberalization of
financial markets in both developed and developing countries. There was,
however, a difference IMF's approach to the so-called 'mature' and
'emerging' markets. Financial liberalization in the developed countries
was an internal and autonomous process driven by the rise to dominance
of finance capital. The IMF merely adopted that programme, having
discovered the 'value' of that regime.
The earnestness with which it subsequently pursued its new-found mission
to open up financial markets in developing countries led to the
criticism that Wall Street, more than even the US Treasury, was
influencing the stance of the IMF. The change in focus from stressing
trade liberalization accompanied by policies aimed at balance of
payments adjustment to emphasizing financial market policies served the
IMF well, since it provided the Fund with a new role in a world of
predominantly private capital flows. The subsequent success of the IMF
in ensuring financial liberalization in developing countries reflected
the new clout it had garnered as a formally unnamed representative of
international finance.
It is surprising, therefore, that in recent months there have seen a
spate of analyses from the IMF that attempt to revisit the experience of
financial liberalization worldwide, and to assess the gains and losses
of liberalization of financial markets in developed and developing
countries over the last decade. This desire to revisit the debate on
financial liberalization has been attributed to two reasons. First,
because there is evidence that the viability of the Anglo-Saxon,
particularly US, model of financial markets and financial policies, is
itself in question. According to the Global Financial Stability Report
released by the Fund in March this year, between the stock
market peak recorded on 24 March 2000 and the end of
February 2003, the S&P 500 stock market index
fell by 45 per cent, the NASDAQ by 73 per cent and the FTSE Euro
top 300 by 55 per cent. This was a period that
witnessed not merely the bursting of the new technology bubble but also
a further decline encouraged by evidence of accounting frauds and market
manipulation. The resultant huge erosion of paper wealth has raised
questions about the appropriateness of organizational forms in the US
financial market.
Second, because of the more damaging evidence that the last
decade-and-a-half, when the wave of financial liberalization was
unleashed in developing countries, have witnessed a series of financial
and currency crises, some of which have been severe. Moreover, analyses
of individual instances of crises have tended to conclude that their
nature and timing had much to do with the shift to a more liberal and
open financial regime. The latest countries to be affected by the
volatility described by the IMF as the 'feast or famine' dynamic are in
Latin America, where two relatively good performers till quite
recently-Argentina and Brazil-have been hit by reduced or
near-negligible access to capital markets. These instances of volatility
followed a spate of crises in developing-country markets in Asia,
Africa, Europe and Latin America during the 1980s and 1990s. Yet, there
were no signs of any rethink on the effects of financial liberalization,
and the prevailing global financial architecture was defended by the
Bretton Woods institutions on the ground that it has served the
objective of economic growth well and requires, if anything, minor
modifications accompanied by institutional strengthening.
However, as mentioned, there have been superficial signs of a change in
attitude more recently. An IMF Working Paper, authored by Graciela
Kaminsky of George Washington University and Sergio Schmukler of the
World Bank, and authorized for distribution in February 2003 by the
IMF's Chief Economist and Research Director Kenneth Rogoff, declares
that findings in the 'crisis literature' suggest that 'booms and busts
in financial markets are at the core of currency crises and that these
large cycles are triggered by financial deregulation’, even though some
of 'the finance literature tend to support the claim that deregulation
is beneficial, with liberalization reducing the cost of capital.’
An IMF study dated 17 March 2003, titled 'Effects of Financial
Globalization on Developing Countries: Some Empirical Evidence’, which
includes Kenneth Rogoff as a co-author, has gone even further. It
recognizes that: (i) 'an objective reading of the vast research effort
to date suggests that there is no strong, robust and uniform support for
the (neoliberal) theoretical argument that financial globalization per
se delivers a higher rate of economic growth’; and (ii) even though
neoliberal theory suggests that 'the volatility of consumption relative
to that of output should go down as the degree of financial integration
increases, since the essence of global financial diversification is that
a country is able to offload some of its income risk in world markets’,
in practice, 'the volatility of consumption growth relative to that of
income growth has on average increased for the emerging market economies
in the 1990s, which was precisely the period of a rapid increase in
financial globalization.’
This new candour on the part of the IMF has not gone unnoticed. The
Financial Times declared that 'the new study marks a continued shift
within the IMF towards much greater caution in encouraging countries to
open up their capital accounts’, necessitated in particular by its
experience in Argentina and Brazil. Another observer remarked: 'The IMF
has just abandoned its fatwa against the unmitigated evil of capital
controls. Institutional confessions of error don't come much bigger than
this one. But while the IMF's many critics are rubbing it in, they
shouldn't forget that such a burst of intellectual honesty takes a lot
of guts.’
The reality behind the IMF's changed attitude is, however, entirely
different. A close reading of both the working paper and the study
referred to indicates that the IMF has decided to accommodate the
growing evidence of the adverse consequences of financial liberalization
in developing countries, not so much to learn from it and revise its
positions but to provide what some view as a more 'nuanced' defence of
financial liberalization. Kaminsky and Schmukler, in fact, argue that
the problem with existing analyses of financial liberalization is that
they separate countries into those that have and those that have not
liberalized their financial markets. In actual fact, countries remove
different kinds of restrictions at different times, which not only leads
to different degrees and patterns of financial liberalization but also
to 'reversal' of the liberalization trend in many contexts.
Once these features of the extent of liberalization of individual
markets are taken account of, they argue, the evidence suggests that
stockmarket booms and busts have not intensified in the long run after
financial liberalization. The real difference between developed and
developing countries is that in the latter, financial liberalization
tends to trigger larger cycles, while in the mature markets, on the
contrary, liberalization is beneficial in the short run as well.
What explains this difference in the case of developing countries? It
is, according to the authors, the fact that institutional reforms aimed
at increasing transparency and appropriate regulation of markets do not
pre-date liberalization. It is only after liberalization is adopted as a
strategy that governments turn their attention to institutional quality,
and therefore the institutional requirements for liberalization to
deliver its beneficial effects are put in place with a lag. This leads
to the paradoxical contrast between the short-run adverse and long-run
beneficial effects of financial liberalization.
The IMF study cited earlier builds on this argument, indicating that the
timing and sequence of the release of the two studies may not be
coincidental. Taking a more nuanced view of liberalization, as does the
Kaminsky–Schmukler paper, the IMF study divides countries into those
that are more and less financially liberalized, not on the basis of the
de jure liberalization suggested by their policies but on the
basis of the de facto liberalization indicated by the volume of
capital inflows and outflows relative to GDP. Thus, if a country has not
adopted liberalization measures to any significant degree but yet has
received large capital inflows, it is treated as a more liberalized
financial market. That is, the link between liberalization and capital
flows is assumed and not established.
Having classified countries in this manner, the study finds that
financial liberalization has no clearly identifiable effect on growth in
developing countries, and that there is evidence that consumption
volatility, in fact, increases with liberalization. However:
'Interestingly, a more nuanced look at the data suggests the possible
presence of a threshold effect. At low levels of financial integration,
an increment in financial integration is associated with an increase in
the relative volatility of consumption. However, once the level of
financial integration crosses a threshold, the association becomes
negative. In other words, for countries that are sufficiently open
financially, relative consumption volatility starts to decline. This
finding is potentially consistent with the view that international
financial integration can help to promote domestic financial sector
development, which in turn can help to moderate domestic macroeconomic
volatility.’
This makes the proliferation of financial and currency crises among
developing economies a natural consequence of
the 'growing pains' associated with financial globalization, and
therefore an inevitable stage they have to undergo to realize the gains
of liberalization. But what causes these short-term crises? The IMF
study itself identifies four factors. First, international investors
have a tendency to engage in momentum trading and herding, that can be
destabilizing. Second, international investors 'may' engage in
speculative attacks on developing-country currencies, leading to
instability that is not warranted by fundamentals. Third, the
'contagion' effect that has been repeatedly observed could result in
international investors withdrawing capital from otherwise healthy
countries. Finally, some governments may not give sufficient weight to
the interest of future generations and exploit financial globalization
to over-borrow, on the basis of purely short-term considerations. All of
these, needless to say, have a mutually reinforcing effect that
exacerbates financial crises when they occur.
It should be obvious that of these factors the first three have more to
do with the behaviour of financial agents from developed countries than
with the behaviour of developing-country governments or financial
agents. Since developing countries can do little about the former, the
case for preempting the effects of such behaviour with financial
controls is strong. Yet, having recognized their importance, the IMF
study goes on to argue: 'The vulnerability of a developing country to
the "risk factors" associated with financial globalization is also not
independent from the quality of macroeconomic policies and domestic
governance. For example, research has demonstrated that an overvalued
exchange rate and an overextended domestic lending boom often precede a
currency crisis. In addition, lack of transparency has been shown to be
associated with more herding behaviour by international investors that
can destabilize a developing country's financial markets. Finally,
evidence shows that a high degree of corruption may affect the
composition of a country's capital inflows in a manner that makes it
more vulnerable to the risks of speculative attacks and contagion
effects.’
Developed industrial countries, the study implicitly suggests, do not
have the institutional features that generate a vicious nexus between
financial liberalization and short-term volatility, leading to periodic
crises. To be like them, developing countries have to cross the
'threshold’, since the greater financial integration that this requires
will automatically lead to improvements in institutional quality as
well. So the implication is not that the developing countries should
give up on financial liberalization but that they should go far enough
to ensure that it is accompanied with by reform that delivers the
institutional quality needed to realize the virtuous relationship
between liberalization and economic performance.
This is indeed surprising, given the factors that led to the collapse of
stockmarkets in the developed countries, especially in the US. As
mentioned earlier, that collapse was exacerbated by conflicts of
interest (as in the Merrill Lynch case), market manipulation (Enron) and
accounting fraud (Enron, WorldCom, Xerox), which does not say much for
either the transparency or quality of US institutions. If it is
institutional quality that accounts for the threshold effect, if any
such exists, then the instances of successful and failed financial
liberalization should not coincide with their categorization as 'mature'
or 'emerging markets’.
The failure of the studies quoted to take account of these factors
points in two directions. First, it suggests that the effort to make a
more 'nuanced' classification of countries into those that are more and
less liberalized amounts to manipulating the evidence to yield results
that defend liberalization in the long term, even though its
consequences are obviously adverse. Second, the new candour is not a
reflection of the need to change track but of the need to ensure that
liberalization is persisted with despite the ostensibly short-run
'pains' of the process. The IMF's case is clear: it does not deny the
volatility, the crises and the pain associated with financial
liberalization; it merely sees them as an inevitable consequence that
must be suffered to enjoy the long-run benefits of liberalization. The
strategy is to assert that the evidence contradicting its case is
actually supportive.
|