Revelations of fraud, evidence of insider trading
and a consequent collapse of investor interest have led to an almost
unstoppable downturn in India's stock markets since the presentation
of the budget. This link with the presentation of the budget is not
coincidental. Judging by the coverage of recent budgets in much of the
print and electronic media, there is a widely prevalent belief that
budgets are best assessed by financial market spokesmen and by their
impact on financial markets. This premium on 'market responses'
(meaning thereby purely financial market responses), even if
overdone, is a fall-out of economic liberalization.
One of the much-emphasized benefits of liberalization
was to be the positive impact it would have on financial inflows into
the country. The reason why speculative financial investments, as opposed
to greenfield foreign direct investment, should be inherently positive
is of course unclear. But let us drop such skepticism for the moment.
The point to note is that the concern with attracting foreign capital
flow has been reflected in the government's fiscal, monetary and
financial policies in recent years. Financial liberalization has not
just permitted, but eased and rendered more attractive foreign financial
investment in India. And budgets have been framed with the intent of
not just satisfying financial investors from abroad but of attracting
them by keeping financial markets buoyant. The spoken responses of financial
agents and the activities as reflected by market indices were therefore
seen even by the Finance Ministry, and not just by the media, as an
indicator of success in budget formulation. This has meant that the
pressure to please financial players has played a major role in shaping
recent budgets though, given the whimsical demands of finance, success
is never guaranteed.
Paradoxically, for the speculator in the stock market
this has provided another counter to bet on. Would the budget trigger
a sharp rise in financial markets, however short-lived or would it not?
Differing answers to that question would elicit different speculative
responses. This was the question which Ketan Parekh, the most recent
incarnation of the perennial 'big bull' in India's stock
markets, had set himself and answered in the positive in February this
year. What ensued is now history.
Expecting to be able to offload stocks of a select
set of companies at higher prices in the wake of the budget, Parekh
built up large positions in these scrips. In normal circumstances, this
very act of investment by a market-mover like Parekh should have provided
a spur to the Sensex. It in fact did. Both just before the budget was
presented and immediately thereafter prices did rise. But that very
signal, gave cause for a bear cartel to turn suspicious. Allegedly consisting
of stock-market insiders, including the BSE chief himself, who in violation
of SEBI norms checked out from the surveillance department who was making
large purchases and of which stocks, this cartel discovered that the
rise in the index was the result of speculative purchases of select
shares. In a world where financial gain, however garnered, is the indicator
of success, the cartel chose to offload large volumes of the very same
stocks acquired at prices much lower than those prevailing in the market
driving prices down.
There must have been a brief period when Parekh struggled
to keep prices of his favourite stocks buoyant in the wake of the bear
hammering. But if he did, his effort obviously failed, paving the way
for the downward descent of all stock market indices. This simple tale
of a speculative bout between bulls and bears in he market turns more
complex and bizarre when a set of related questions begin to be asked
and the consequences of the market collapse begin to be assessed.
Let's begin with the related questions. What
explains the fact that a few operators, who in one way or another are
market insiders, can make and break India's much celebrated financial
markets? Analysts attribute this to the fact that markets in developing
countries like India are thin or shallow in at least three senses. First,
only stocks of a few companies are actively traded in the market. Second,
of these stocks there is only a small proportion that is routinely available
for trading, with the rest being held by promoters, the financial institutions
and others interested in corporate control or influence. And, third
the number of players trading these stocks are also few in number. According
to to the Report of the SEBI's Committee on Market Making, The
number of shares listed on the BSE since 1994 has remained almost around
5800 taking into account delisting and new listing. While the number
of listed shares remained constant, the aggregate trading volume on
the exchange increased significantly. For example, the average daily
turnover, which was around Rs.500 crore in January 1994 increased to
Rs.1000 crores in August 1998. But, despite this increase in turnover,
there has not been a commensurate increase in the number of actively
traded shares. On the contrary, the number of shares not traded even
once in a month on the BSE has increased from 2199 shares in January
1997 to 4311 shares in July 1998. The net impact is that speculation
and volatility are essential features of such markets. According to
one analyst, the role of speculation is visible in the high ratio (3:1)
of trading volumes to market capitalization in what is otherwise a shallow
market.
These features of the market have a number of implications.
To start with, Foreign Institutional Investors (FIIs), whose exposure
in Indian markets is an extremely small share of their international
potfolio, making India almost irrelevant to their international strategies,
have an undue influence on the performance of markets in India. The
sums they invest or withdraw can move markets in the upward and downward
direction, as recent experience has amply demonstrated. This forces
government's keen to have them constantly making net purchases
and driving markets upwards to bend over backwards in appeasing them.
A corollary of this influence of the FIIs is that any market player
who is able to mobilize a significant sum of capital and is willing
to risk it in investments in the market can be a major influence on
market performance. This explains the importance of operators like Harshad
Mehta and Ketan Parekh, the big bulls of the 1990s, who rose from being
small traders to become crorepatis and were lionized for their
resource mobilization and risk-taking abilities, which made them movers
of markets. Ketan Parekh is reported to have risked his investments
on a few sectors (the so-called technology stocks) and few firms, and
till the recent debacle, always seemed to come out rights in terms of
his judgements. He had, it now appears, a major role to play in rigging
share prices, as he allegedly did in the case of Global Trust Bank shares
prior to the aborted merger of UTI Bank and GTB.
This brings to the fore the second related set of
questions concerns. What were and are the sources of funds of these
domestic bulls who take risks and drive markets, for at least some time,
and of the bears who on occasion even hammer them out of business? Brokers
we must recall deal only marginally with their own resources. Their
primary role is to convince investors to provide them funds to realize
strategies they believe would yield quick and large returns. Media reports
on the events that led to Ketan Parekh's fall from grace have focused
on the funds he fraudulently acquired from the Bank of India and other
commercial banks. That story is now well known. Parekh was issued pay-orders,
which are in the nature of demand drafts, by the Ahmedabad-based Madhavpura
Mercantile Cooperative Bank (MCCB), without any reciprocal pay-in of
funds either directly in the form of cash or indirectly in the form
of deposits that could serve as collateral for a loan. This was not
without any reason. In the past MMCB must have benefited immensely from
its association with Parekh, as is evident from reports suggesting that
its total exposure to Parekh was in the range of Rs. 800 crore. Clearly
Parekh and the MMCB management saw the issue of around Rs. 200 crore
worth of pay-orders as a form of temporary accommodation that would
be made good by Parekh as soon as his speculative trades had been completed.
A reading of Budget 2001, which provides a range of sops to render markets
buoyant, does in fact suggest that his gamble was not all to wild. It
failed, rendering the MMCB pay-orders worthless, not so much because
of the judgment on which it was based but because of the concerted move
by the bear cartel to exploit unfairly obtained knowledge of Parekh's
maneuvers by dumping shares on which Parekh was placing his bets.
But, given Parekh's access to resources and acumen,
he must have made an attempt to counter these moves of the cartel. Hence,
the collapse in prices could be explained only by ability of these operators
to supply an adequately large sum of these and related shares. What
then was the source of the riches of the bear cartel, which finally
won out? While a final judgment on the matter must await the SEBI's
report on its investigation, there are a number of strands of the answer
that have been revealed. Being regular operators, it is quite possible
that the bear operators had in their pool significant amounts of these
crucial stocks, not necessarily belonging to them, but which they were
trading on behalf of the investors they represented. It is true that
under the recently framed rules relating to trading and settlement
in dematerialized form, these stocks have to be lodged with a depository
against the name of the actual owner. However, in practice many brokers
carry large volumes of stocks in their pool accounts. Various reasons
such as use of stocks as margin deposits by clients, delay in the flow
of instructions from the client's depository participant to the
brokers depository participant and intentions to sell in the subsequent
settlement period have been used by broking houses to explain away they
unusually large pool accounts. In the event, there are a large number
of in-transit shares that brokers have access to, even if they do not
have legal ownership right to trade in them.
This pool, however, does not limit the trading ability
of the bear cartel. It could use a number of avenues afforded by stock-market
rules, framed in the wake of liberalization, to increase liquidity in
the market. One such is the practice of borrowing and lending stocks.
Under the Securities Lending Scheme introduced in 1997, holders of stocks
lodged with the depository, like the Stockholding Corporation of India
Ltd (SHCIL), could come to an agreement, implemented through the intermediary,
to lend these stocks to others for a specified period of time for an
interest. Some stocks holders like the FIIs and institutions like the
UTI and the insurance companies often have large volumes of individual
stocks in their kitty. So long as members of the bear cartel have information
as to which players have large volumes of specific stocks, they can
work out a deal to borrow these shares, providing them access to them
even if they do not have the right to trade in them.
Knowledge of the existence and source of the required
shares can encourage the practice of short-selling, or sale of shares
not owned by the trader, in the belief that prices are going down and
the shares can be made good to the actual owner by buying them back
at much lower prices at a later date. That this practice was resorted
to by the bear cartel is clear from the fact that the SEBI decided to
ban short-sales in the wake of the collapse in stock indices in March.
Thus the bear cartel clearly required litlle by way of own resources
to indulge in the activities that led up to the collapse of markets.
The bear cartel's activity borders on bravado
because of the consequences that the slump in prices resulting from
its actions have had. First, to the extent that bulls like Parekh suffered
losses, they needed to settle their dues with additional resources.
In Parekh's case the dues where ostensibly the wherewithal needed
to ensure that Madhavpura Mercantile Cooperative Bank (MCCB) could honour
the pay-orders it had issued to him without any downpayment either in
the form of cash or deposit collateral. In other cases, brokers had
expected to settle dues either through sales of shares they held or
borrowing against those shares. Settlement requires a pay-in
by those who accept deliveries of scrips that they have agreed to buy,
and a pay-out to those who have submitted the shares for delivery as
agreed. Delayed settlement possibilities, permissible under the modified
carry-forward scheme (MCFS) operating in India's stock markets
can lead to settlement problems because they encourage excessively high
speculative positions on the part of brokers expecting to be able to
realize the required funds when settlement day arrives. But, in many
cases the collapse in the interim of the value of the shares they hold
make the settlement impossible to ensure, leading to payments problems,
which were particularly acute in the Calcutta Stock Exchange, located
faraway from the centre of Parekh's activities.
Second, the effects of the speculative collapse soon
spread to the banking system. To start with, banks like MCCB which had
accommodated the loser and others that had invested in MCCB or had made
large deposits with it for services such as clearing services, which
includes a number of other cooperative banks in Gujarat, found themselves
saddled with worthless real or intangible assets, resulting in weakness
of a kind that triggered a run on these banks. Further, even regular
commercial banks which had lent against shares as collateral found that
the value of that collateral had fallen substantially relative to the
sums lent, forcing them to demand an increase in collateral to protect
loans which were made in many cases to brokers who had suffered losses
in the wake of the bear hammering. The full effects of the scam on the
banks, and the distribution of loss provisions amongst them would be
revealed only after some time. What needs to be noted is that once the
process of divesting public equity in banks proceeds further this can
have larger implications. Even now, the shares of a number of public
sector banks that have diluted their equity are ruling below par. If
the same occurs in the wake of large scale dilution, they would be ideal
candidates for take-over as part of process of financial consolidation
that would put control of large volumes of household savings in a few
hands.
Third, small investors holding safe securities either
directly or indirectly through agencies like mutual funds find the value
of their investments eroded for reasons that are neither legally valid
or within their control or even ken. This would legitimately undermine
their faith in stock investments. But this occurs precisely at a time
when a liberalization-driven effort to cut interest rates on long term
deposits and small savings schemes is forcing them to participate in
the markets.
Finally, this loss of faith in stock markets is only
being aggravated by the fact that the viability of these markets is
being challenged by the consequences of speculative losses. Faced with
settlement problems, and unable to indefinitely postpone settlement,
the Calcutta Stock Exchange has found even its Settlement Guarantee
Fund (SGF) inadequate to cover the short fall. The management of the
exchange has managed to save face only by getting some 'friendly'
financial institutions to pick up large volumes of stock at a discount
to provide brokers the funds needed to meet their settlement obligations.
All of this reveals the fragility of the financial
system that is being provided greater room for maneuverability by the
financial liberalization that seeks to attract foreign investors into
India's shallow markets. What is more, by increasing maneuverability
and by allowing banks to indirectly support trading activity, and by
privileging stock market buoyancy as an indicator of economic success,
liberalization is increasing speculative activity and aggravating the
fragility of the system. In the effort to shift the focus away from
the folly of liberalizing markets so prone to speculation, the government
is now pointing its fingers at the inadequacies of the regulatory authority.
What is missed is that the ethos of liberalization which gives financial
markets pride of place in assessments of the success of economic policy
forces the regulatory authority to be flexible and even formulate rules
providing room for maneuver to private operators in order to keep markets
buoyant even when the real economy slows. The point to note is that
the only players who need these markets are the speculators, a few large corporates and, of course, the FIIs who in the wake of the collapse
are busy picking up shares at huge discounts.
|