Your
Excellency the Chancellor of the University, Mr
Vice-Chancellor, Assembled Guests, Members of the
Faculty, Young Scholars, Ladies and Gentlemen,
It is a singular honour for me to have been invited as
the chief guest at the convocation of this university
which, though young in age, has built up for itself an
enviable academic reputation. This achievement is due
partly no doubt to the ethos of West Bengal: even as
the academic ambience over much of the country has
deteriorated sharply, West Bengal continues to produce
a steady stream of exceptionally fine young scholars
who are much in demand at home and abroad. But it also
owes much to the dedication and commitment of the
faculty members, with many of whom I can claim
personal acquaintance. It gives me particular pleasure
to be amongst them on this happy occasion.
The importance for our national life of institutions
such as this one, indeed of higher education in
general, is often not appreciated. Some even argue
that institutions of higher education constitute a
white elephant, a drain on the nation’s resources
which can be better deployed in promoting the spread
of elementary education in the country. Instead of the
pyramidal structure we should have built up, of a
broad base of elementary education supporting a
smaller apex of higher education, we have actually
built up, they contend, a top-heavy structure where a
plethora of colleges and universities has grown up
within a vast ocean of illiteracy and ignorance.
This argument, whose proponents include many
progressive and sensitive thinkers, is, nonetheless,
fundamentally flawed. There can of course be no two
views on the urgent need for eradicating illiteracy
and enlarging the spread of elementary education. In
fact it is a national shame that even after half a
century of independence, more than one-third of the
population in the country remains illiterate, and
around two-fifths of children of school-going age
remain outside the ambit of formal schooling at any
given time. The mistake consists in believing that an
absolute curtailment (or even a curtailment relative
to GDP) of expenditure on higher education is
necessary for overcoming these failures. The shortage
of resources that is usually cited in this context as
a constraint is a mere alibi.
I shall discuss what has been happening on the
resource front in the more recent period later in the
course of my address. But the crucial point is this:
at no stage during the entire post-independence period
has India spent an adequate amount on education, by
any reasonable definition of the term ‘adequate’.
In fact the proportion of GDP that the
white-supremacist South African state spent on the
education of the black majority even during the
apartheid period, notwithstanding the massive drain on
its exchequer that maintenance of the highly
oppressive police, military and intelligence apparatus
entailed at the time, was higher than what the Indian
state has ever spent throughout its post-independence
history. The matter, in short, is one of
priorities. Any government that has the political will
to eradicate illiteracy and provide universal primary
education would always find the resources for doing so
without curtailing higher education. And any
government that complains of lack of resources and
considers it necessary to starve higher education in
order to provide for the spread of literacy and
primary education simply lacks ipso facto the
political will for effecting universal literacy and
primary education.
While strengthening higher education does not preclude
in any way the expansion of elementary education, such
strengthening is essential for the development of the
country, indeed for the very survival of the freedom
of its people. The realm of higher education is the
cradle of ideas; the shrinking or extinction of this
realm necessarily makes a society parasitic on others
for its ideas, and such a parasitic society cannot
remain free.
John Maynard Keynes, the greatest economist of the
twentieth century, may have exaggerated a trifle when
he wrote: ‘... the ideas of economists and political
philosophers, both when they are right and when they
are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly
understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else.’
But the exaggeration is no more than a trifle. After
all Bertolt Brecht, coming from a very different
segment of the political spectrum, also wrote: ‘Hungry
man, reach for the book!’ The hungry man, however,
must reach for the right book, one that tells him not
that his chronic hunger is the result of sins
committed in some previous birth but educates him
instead on the social conditions that keep him hungry.
This presupposes that the right book must be
available, that the crowd of hungry men must have
their own ‘organic intellectuals’ whose ideas must
develop independently of the ideas of those who
preside over a social arrangement that keeps the
hungry, hungry. Independent institutions of higher
education are essential for this. To be sure, having
such institutions is not a sufficient condition for
the development of independent ideas that are relevant
for the life, freedom and progress of a particular
society. But it is a necessary condition.
The mass mobilization that constituted our freedom
struggle would not have been possible if the
intellectual groundwork for it had not been done by
pioneering thinkers like Dadabhai Naoroji and Romesh
Chandra Dutt, who dared to think independently of the
prevailing theoretical constructs in the institutions
of higher learning in the metropolitan countries. This
tradition of independent thinking is necessary also
for defending the gains of our freedom struggle. Since
we are now in a position to have our own institutions
where the conditions for independent thinking can
prevail as a matter of course, we must develop and
nurture such institutions.
II
Implicit
in what I have just said is a whole series of
rejections. First, there is rejection of the view that
different institutions of higher learning belonging to
different societies can be ordered as being ‘better’
or ‘worse’ along one particular axis. If these
institutions are to be ‘organic’ to their specific
societies, then, since the interests of these
societies are quite obviously not in harmony, each set
of institutions must be different from the others in
order to fulfil its legitimate role. I often feel
amused when I hear comments like ‘Kalyani University
(or Jawaharlal Nehru University, for that matter)
should imitate Harvard’; ‘Our institutions should
enrich themselves by borrowing ideas and faculty from
advanced country institutions’; ‘We have to judge
ourselves by how well we are recognized by top
institutions in the world’, and so on. This whole
approach, to my mind, is wrong. It sees higher
education as a homogeneous commodity of which some
institutions are better producers than others, and not
as a means of producing ‘organic intellectuals’ for a
particular society. I referred above to Dadabhai
Naoroji and R.C. Dutt, whose contribution to the
struggle for the freedom of our society was enormous.
But scarcely any one in Harvard or Cambridge doing
economics would have heard of them (though those doing
‘India studies’ might have). Modelling our
institutions after Harvard or Cambridge, which would
entail copying their curricula and syllabi, would
therefore necessarily mean sacrificing, to our great
cost, the conceptual framework, perspective and
insights of a thinker like Naoroji.
Second, my argument rejects the view that
professionalization of subjects like ‘economics’ and
‘political science’ is a desirable process. The
‘profession’ in these disciplines, as well as in
others, is dominated by the advanced countries;
therefore recognition in the ‘profession’ would
necessarily mean sacrificing any independent thinking
and parroting borrowed concepts. This would not matter
if these borrowed concepts were genuinely ‘scientific’
and not imbued with the ideological objective of
defending the hegemony of the advanced countries. In
the social sciences at least, as I shall illustrate
later, such is not the case. This does not mean that
everyone engaged in social science research in
universities in the advanced countries is a conscious
ideological defender of imperialist hegemony, but
everyone is entrapped by the need to belong to and be
recognized by the ‘profession’, and therefore
undertakes research within strictly circumscribed
limits which preclude any critical awareness of the
role of the handed-down conceptual apparatus in the
ideological defence of imperialist hegemony. Stepping
out of these limits invites reactions of unease,
astonishment, silence, derision and even hostility,
resulting in a loss of academic and financial status.
Hence even the best-intentioned dare not step beyond
the limits. In societies like ours where domination of
the western theoretical orthodoxy in the social
sciences is far from complete, thanks precisely to our
rather recent birth as a nation after a prolonged
anti-imperialist struggle, any emphasis on
‘professionalization’ would mean voluntarily
surrendering ourselves to this domination, closing the
space has been made available to us for independent
thought.
Third, my argument entails a rejection of the attitude
which places a special value on ‘recognition’ in the
advanced countries, and hence on awards and
distinctions bestowed from there. In the social
sciences, at any rate, all such awards and
distinctions are conditional on conformity, on keeping
within the ‘limits’ and abjuring the use of concepts
that critique imperialist hegemony. Unfortunately,
this attitude of prioritizing ‘recognition’ in the
west is all too pervasive in our country. Almost all
of us, when we sit on Selection Committees, prefer a
candidate who has published in a western journal over
one who has published within the country, even without
looking closely at the quality of the two
publications. By doing so, we contribute to a
stultification of the tradition of independent
thinking.
To say this is not to reject the notion of quality, or
to argue that we should not have criteria for judging
quality. But these criteria must be our own, and not
those employed in the institutions of advanced
countries. Developing these criteria, to be sure, is
not easy, but there is no escape from the need to do
so if we are to preserve a tradition of independent
thinking.
III
Let me
give an example, drawn from my own discipline,
economics, to underscore the necessity of a tradition
of thought independent of the prevailing orthodoxy in
the west. One consequence of the policy of
‘liberalization’ has been the relaxation of
restrictions on the flow of finance into and out of
the country, because of which it so happens that a
significant inflow of foreign exchange has taken place
of late. To prevent the exchange rate from
appreciating, the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) has
intervened to buy up the foreign exchange that has
been coming in, and as a result we currently have
exchange reserves of nearly $90 billion. Now, holding
such large reserves is not a sensible thing to do.
Foreign exchange reserves are nothing else but IOUs of
other countries; hence holding such IOUs represents a
waste of resources that could be more productively
used elsewhere. What is more, since the rate of return
that those bringing funds into the country earn is
higher than the rate earned on these reserves (which
is a trivial amount), the country in effect is
borrowing from abroad at a higher rate to lend at a
lower rate. This is palpably unwise.
In this connection, suggestions have been made by the
Bretton Woods institutions, and by independent
analysts, including academics, in western financial
journals, that India should allow its exchange rate to
appreciate, and that towards this end the RBI should
stop adding to its reserves but lower them instead.
Several Indian academics and financial journalists
have also endorsed this idea. Let us look at the
implications of such a move.
If the rupee appreciates, the competitiveness of our
goods vis-à-vis foreign goods is lowered through a
cheapening of foreign goods. Since such an
appreciation would not expand the total domestic
demand, this relative cheapening of foreign goods
would mean that a given volume of domestic demand
would be met by foreign goods rather than by domestic
goods; likewise, our exports would be supplanted in
outside markets by foreign countries’ exports. It
follows that an appreciation of the rupee would lead
to a closure of domestic producing units and to higher
unemployment, together with an increase in our trade
(and current account) deficit (which is in fact how
the reserves would have got used up). We would have,
in short, unleashed a process of ‘debt-financed
deindustrialization’, i.e. borrowed to finance the
ruination of our own production base. What is more,
when the time comes for foreigners (or non-resident
Indians) who are now bringing finance into the economy
to start taking it out, we would have no funds left to
cover the outflow, since these would have been used
meanwhile in financing imports at the expense of home
production. Thus, frittering away foreign exchange
reserves through an appreciation of the rupee would
mean ruination of the country twice over: through
deindustrialization and unemployment now, and
bankruptcy later.
This of course would work to the advantage of foreign,
especially metropolitan, countries: they would obtain
larger markets now, which, given the prevailing
recessionary conditions, they desperately need (it is
noteworthy that a similar demand for revaluing the
exchange rate upwards is being made with regard to
China); and they would be able to impose whatever
‘conditionalities’ they choose in the future, when our
country, in order to finance capital outflows,
approaches them or agencies like the IMF and the World
Bank dominated by them, for loans. It is not
surprising then that the western press, the Bretton
Woods institutions and many western academics are
demanding an appreciation of the rupee. But to oppose
this demand, to avoid this double ruin, and to protect
our sovereignty and freedom, it is essential that
there be people within the country who think
independently and have the capacity to see the
implications of such moves.
If, it may be asked, holding large reserves is unwise
and getting rid of reserves through an appreciation of
the rupee even more so, what should the country do?
Obviously, if there was an agency that undertook
productive investment either using the reserves or on
the strength of these reserves, i.e. using these as
cushion (since plenty of unutilized domestic
industrial capacity also exists), then they would have
been put to some good use. The only such agency can be
the state (since capitalists’ investment decisions are
spurred by their own calculations and cannot be
stimulated just because the country has a plethora of
unused resources). True, even if the state undertook
investment on the strength of these reserves and used
up a substantial chunk of them, when the time comes
for finance to flow out the country may still find
itself short of funds (unless the investment
undertaken in the meantime earns sufficient foreign
exchange). Some degree of control over capital flows,
therefore, would have to supplement larger state
investment. In short, a combination of capital
controls and larger state investment is required if
the country is to cope with the burgeoning capital
inflows.
But both these are anathema as far as the theoretical
orthodoxy in the west is concerned. There may of late
have been some grudging admission of the need for
capital controls, but larger state investment is
taboo, especially for third world economies. The only
reasonable way of coping with financial inflows is
thus closed to us if we follow the lead of the
dominant theoretical orthodoxy in my discipline. This
fact only underscores the absolute need for
independent thinking in societies like ours.
Of course, simply having institutions of higher
education does not mean that this need gets
automatically fulfilled. A whole range of measures
have to be undertaken to ensure that these
institutions play the role that they should; but that
is a separate, albeit vital, issue. Not having any
such institutions completely forecloses the
possibilities of any independent thought.
IV
The
pressure for ‘professionalization’ is one persistent
factor working towards the destruction of independent
thought, and thwarting the emergence of institutions
capable of producing ‘organic intellectuals’ for our
society. In addition to this, two other specific
factors have emerged in recent years which work in the
same direction. The first is the tendency towards
privatization which has gathered momentum on account
of the fiscal crisis of the state. This crisis existed
even earlier, but it has become greatly accentuated by
the pursuit of ‘neoliberal’ policies at the behest of
the Bretton Woods institutions since the beginning of
the 1990s.
The fiscal constraints on an economy pursuing
neoliberal policies are obvious. Since
‘liberalization’ must include trade liberalization,
customs duties must be brought down; since the state
which lowers customs duties cannot simultaneously
increase excise duties (for otherwise it precipitates
gratuitous deindustrialization by favouring imports
over home production), its capacity to raise revenues
from indirect taxation as a whole gets reduced. To
entice foreign capital, which is supposed to play a
central role in ushering in development, it must lower
direct taxes on such capital (whether or not foreign
capital actually comes), for otherwise capital would
go to destinations with lower tax rates. To maintain
some inter se equity between foreign and
domestic capital, the latter also cannot be taxed too
heavily, so that corporate tax revenue shrinks
relatively, which cannot be offset, again for reasons
of inter se equity, through larger personal
income taxes. It follows that the logic of a
‘liberalized’ economy is to reduce the tax–GDP ratio.
This in fact is what has happened in a
host of economies adopting neoliberal economic
policies, and India is no exception. If we take
triennium averages, there was a reduction of 1.6 per
cent in the ratio of central gross tax revenue to GDP,
and 1.3 per cent in central net tax revenue to GDP
between the triennia centred on 1990–91 and 1999–2000.
Even taking the lower of these figures it turns out
that if only the same tax–GDP
ratio had been maintained at the end of the decade as
prevailed at the beginning, prior to ‘liberalization’,
the central government would have garnered an
additional revenue of Rs 26,000 crore in a single
year.
There is an additional fall-out of ‘liberalization’.
It invariably entails an increase in the rate of
interest that the government has to pay on its
borrowings. An estimate for India, for instance,
suggests that the increase in the interest burden of
the public exchequer on this score, even without
taking into account the compounding effects of higher
interest rates, was as much as Rs 13000 crore in
2001–02. The total drain on the central government
exchequer of both these measures therefore amounted to
about Rs 40,000 crore at the end of the decade of the
1990s, compared to the beginning of the decade. And
the centre ‘passed on’ this ‘drain’ to the state
governments, making the latter’s fiscal situation
precarious.
The effect of all this, together with the fact that
the fiscal deficit under the neoliberal dispensation
is supposed to be kept under strict control, is a
curtailment in total government expenditure, which has
a particular impact on expenditure on social sectors
like education and health, and which unleashes in turn
a tendency towards privatization of these sectors.
The implication of privatization, which necessarily
brings in a profit-motive into the sphere of
education, has been missed by many, including several
sensitive thinkers who see no harm in it. If education
becomes a business, it loses its capacity to produce
‘organic intellectuals’ for the people. Education is
not a homogeneous good, like steel or cement, which
can be produced by the public and private sectors
alike. Education, seen as the product of educational
institutions, is fundamentally heterogeneous.
Education that enables a person to get a well-paid job
in the existing job market is not the same as
education that produces an ‘organic intellectual’ of
the people (a distinction analogous to the one that
Paul Baran drew between the ‘intellect worker’ and the
‘intellectual’). To draw this distinction is not to
say that ‘organic intellectuals’ of the people should
be incapable of obtaining a job in the job market; the
point, rather, is that even while imparting education
to enable persons to obtain jobs and serve the country
as ‘intellect workers’, education must
simultaneously ensure that they do not remain mere
‘intellect workers’ but also become ‘intellectuals’,
in the sense of ‘organic intellectuals’ of the people.
Privatization of education produces exclusively
‘intellect workers’, and no ‘intellectuals’.
The matter can be put somewhat differently.
Privatization turns education into a commodity where
the buyer’s preference must necessarily enter to
determine the nature of the commodity produced. There
is a basic difference between education that satisfies
the preference of the buyer and education that is
undertaken in the interests of the people. If
education is to be undertaken in the interests of the
people, to defend their interests, it must be
publicly financed. If it ceases to be publicly
financed, the education that increasingly gets to be
produced is one that is intrinsically incapable of
serving the interests of the people. (To say this is
not to ask for a ban on private institutions of higher
education but to emphasize the need for a
predominantly public educational system, into which
private institutions must fit. The modalities of where
and how they can fit in have to be carefully worked
out.)
But then, it may be asked quite pertinently: how can
we ignore altogether the dictates of the market? In an
era of the IT revolution we have to have people with
IT expertise. Universities consequently have to orient
themselves towards imparting knowledge on IT rather
than continuing to emphasize traditional subjects like
the liberal arts and producing unemployable graduates
even as the country misses out on the new technology
that is unfolding. In other words, the market is a
signalling device which indicates changing demands
that are by no means socially irrelevant. Ignoring the
dictates of the market, therefore, is a perilous
venture for any society.
It seems to me, however, that the objective of higher
education that I have been outlining is perfectly
compatible with the other purpose which education
serves, namely, to impart skills, the nature of which
changes with changing technology. Sensitivity to the
latter need is not synonymous with the commoditization
of education. The point at issue is the exclusive
determination of educational priorities by the market.
Privatization of education has a tendency to lead to
such exclusive determination not just in the
privatized segment, but in the sphere of higher
education as a whole, through the pressures it brings
to bear on the non-privatized segment.
Some contend that if the state is afflicted by a
fiscal crisis, it ipso facto implies that the
people are not paying for producing ‘organic
intellectuals’ for their own cause, i.e. they have
implicitly ‘voted’ not to have such ‘intellectuals’.
Too many tears should not, therefore, be shed over
this fact, for the people themselves want it this way.
It is not the ordinary people in the country, however,
who have been the beneficiaries of the reduction in
the tax–GDP ratio which underlies the fiscal crisis.
On the contrary, while the tax concessions have gone
in favour of the rich, the ordinary people, especially
in rural India, have suffered from the effects of
deflation via unemployment and cuts in social
expenditures. They are not the votaries but the
victims of these cuts. Privatizing higher education in
this context has the effect not only of excluding them
from its ambit, but also of muting whatever
intellectual opposition exists against the policies
that victimize them.
The need for nurturing such intellectual opposition
arises not out of charity, or out of a mere
transcendental commitment to democracy and
egalitarianism. It is essential for social peace,
indeed for social survival. Society can ignore this
need only at its own peril, for in the absence of an
intellectual articulation of the plight of the
victims, in the absence of ‘organic intellectuals’ who
can provide such articulation, the opposition of the
victims to their plight takes on highly destructive,
socially debilitating, and extreme and unproductive
forms, such as terrorism, which cause much suffering,
usually pointless suffering, all round.
V
One
cannot be critical only of privatization of higher
education without raising one's voice against another
phenomenon that has been quite pervasive until now,
namely the appropriation for purely private ends of
public education. I have in mind the fact that a large
proportion of the products of prestigious institutions
of higher learning in our country, such as the IITs
and medical institutes like AIIMS and PGIMR, whose
education is financed in large measure by the ordinary
Indian masses, who are among the poorest people in the
world, then migrate to the advanced capitalist
countries to make a comfortable living for themselves.
I do not blame them for one instant. But I do blame
our successive governments for having turned a blind
eye to this phenomenon and permitted the continuation
of a state of affairs where the poorest in the world
are made to subsidize the health system of the richest
in the world. Even if no restrictions on emigration
are placed, at the very least a minimum period of
service in India could be demanded, or a refunding out
of their sumptuous salaries abroad, of the expenses
incurred by the country on their education. Nothing of
the sort has been imposed, and the country has handed
over gratis, skilled persons trained at the
people’s expense, to advanced countries.
What is more, they have been lionized, notwithstanding
their choice to leave the country. Their paltry
contributions, setting up a hospital here or donating
some money to their alma mater there, have been
much heralded by the media and the government; by
contrast, they have been resoundingly silent on the
massive transfers, amounting now to well over $10
billion per annum, by poor Malayalee Muslim migrants
to the Gulf, which have been a major prop of our
balance of payments. In the case of the other
migrants, skilled doctors and engineers, whose
transfers have been paltry, we have a clear case of
private appropriation of public resources. The fault
here lies not with the appropriators but with those
who allow it. Their lionization, moreover, amounts to
encouragement of such appropriation. It is imperative
that the struggle against privatization of education
be complemented by a struggle against such
privatization of public resources in the sphere of
education.
VI
The
second factor which works in the direction of
enfeebling the generation of ‘organic intellectuals’
in our society is the increasing sway of communal and
obscurantist forces over the sphere of education.
These forces, at any rate segments of them, often
claim to be fighting the ‘western’ influence on our
education system (two names that figure in their
perception of the ‘evil trinity’ being Marx and
Macaulay). Paradoxically, however, they end up
strengthening the very ‘western influence’ that they
claim to be fighting. Their attempt at the
introduction of courses in state-funded universities
to turn out purohits and astrologers, on the
explicit argument that there is a market demand for
them, is as much a ‘commoditization’ of education as
the demand for capitation fees and the substitution of
basic disciplines by more ‘marketable’ subjects.
Likewise, their attempt to change textbooks to make
them conform to the prejudices of a handful of bigots
on the ground that nothing offensive to the ‘religious
sentiments’ of the ‘majority community’ should be
carried in such books, is antithetical to the spirit
of scientific inquiry without which there can be no
‘intellectuals’, let alone ‘organic intellectuals’ of
the people. The retreat to prejudice, the promotion of
obscurantism, the substitution of extraneous criteria
for scientific investigation in evaluating the worth
of academic propositions—all of these entail a
devaluation of the content of higher education which
actually disarms the country intellectually against
the onslaught of imperialist ideology. At a political
level, communalism and fundamentalism divide the
people and contribute to a weakening of the nation
vis-à-vis imperialism; at an intellectual level, they
make a parallel contribution by obliterating the
intellectual capacity to see through their
machinations. Opposition to the ideology of
imperialism, one must remember, was provided by an
inclusive Indian nationalism that was secular,
democratic and self-confessed by socialist.
Communalism, whether of the Hindu or the Muslim
variety, never had an anti-imperialist thrust. Should
it come as any surprise, then, that the emergence of
communal politics and ideology also paves the way for
reassertion of the hegemony of the imperialist
ideology?
VII
I have
gone on long enough. Even though a degree of ritual
sermonizing is de rigeur on occasions such as
this, nonetheless these are basically happy occasions,
occasions for celebration: for the university for
completing yet another fruitful year, and for the
young scholars for entering into a new life and new
responsibilities. Now that I have done my bit of
obligatory sermonizing, I wish to join you in the
celebrations. May I warmly congratulate the young
scholars who are receiving their degrees today and
wish this university many more years of productive,
distinguished and fruitful life? Thank you for your
attention.
Prabhat Patnaik
|