The theoretical perception underlying the strategy of
the 2001-2 budget can be summed up as follows: the
recession that currently afflicts the economy is a
result inter alia of the high real rate of interest
that prevails, which in turn is caused by the high
level of the fiscal deficit. Controlling the fiscal
deficit therefore holds the key to economic revival,
and this is what the budget sets out to do.
The proposition that the size of the fiscal deficit
affects the level of the interest rate, which is
advanced by the Bretton Woods institutions, is
beginning to gain currency among Indian economists,
including many who would not consider themselves to be
votaries of "liberalisation". This proposition, it
cannot be denied, has an appealing simplicity: a
fiscal deficit means fresh demand for loans by the
government, and hence an increase in the supply of
government securities; this increase, it stands to
reason, must lead to a fall in the prices of
securities in general, i.e. a rise in the interest
rate. This apparently ' obvious' proposition however
is theoretically completely erroneous, which in turn
makes the budgetary strategy fundamentally flawed. Let
us see why.
I
The statement that an increase in the supply of
government securities must lower security prices in
general, requires the assumption that the total demand
for securities is given (or, more generally, the
demand curve for securities as a function of the
interest rate, even if not vertical, is given). But
this assumption is incorrect : a fiscal deficit
increases not only the supply of securities, but also
their demand, i.e. it shifts both the demand and the
supply curves outwards. Just as investment generates
(in a closed economy) an amount of savings equal to
itself at any given level of the interest rate,
likewise a fiscal deficit invariably generates (in a
closed economy) an amount of private excess savings
(i.e. an excess of private savings over private
investment) equal to itself, at any given level of the
interest rate. In a situation where the real economy
is demand-constrained, this happens through an
increase in output (or through a decumulation of
unwanted stocks); but even if the situation is one of
supply constraint, this happens through inflationary
forced savings, i.e. through a rise in prices relative
to money wages.
One can put the matter differently. An economy must
reach both a flow equilibrium where savings and
investment are equal, and a stock equilibrium where
economic agents are satisfied with the form in which
they hold their wealth. The stock equilibrium in other
words arises because economic agents have a choice
regarding the form in which they hold their wealth,
e.g whether they hold a direct claim on capital stock
(bonds and equity) or an indirect claim mediated
through the banking system (money). To say that a rise
in the fiscal deficit raises the interest rate, which
logically amounts to saying that the interest rate is
determined by the demand for and the supply of
savings, i.e. that it is determined exclusively by the
flow equilibrium (since both savings and investment
are flows), is to deny that economic agents have a
choice regarding the form of holding wealth, which is
absurd. If this choice is denied, and economic agents
are invariably assumed to hold their wealth only
directly, in the form of capital stock (or claims upon
capital stock), then the possibility of full
employment savings not being invested is ruled out by
assumption. It follows that anyone who believes that a
rise in the fiscal deficit necessarily raises the
interest rate, must, to be logically consistent, also
believe that the system can never be
demand-constrained, i.e. is always at full employment
(in the Keynesian sense), which is palpably absurd.
II
The Prime Minister's Economic Advisory Council (PMEAC)
in its recent report has put forward an argument which
is slightly different from the one presented above,
though belonging to the same genre. This argument
states: "The consequences of a high fiscal deficit
depend upon the way the deficit is financed." If the
deficit is financed by monetisation, and if this
monetisation is "excessive", then this leads to
domestic inflationary pressure, whose "impact is the
highest on the poor." On the other hand if the deficit
is financed by "borrowing in domestic financial
markets" then "the result is that real interest rates
become very high" which chokes off private investment.
The PMEAC's argument is different from the one
presented above because it does not assert that an
increase in real interest rates is the inevitable
consequence of a rise in the fiscal deficit; the
consequence according to it depends on how the deficit
is financed. But this proposition, namely that the
consequences of a fiscal deficit are determined by how
it is financed, flies in the face of elementary
economics, as can be seen from simple IS-LM analysis.
Consider the first case
mentioned by the PMEAC, the case of monetisation. Even
if the deficit is financed by monetisation which adds
to bank reserves, this need not cause an inflationary
squeeze on the poor as long as the real economy is
demand-constrained to start with, and the deficit is
not large enough to cause it to become
supply-constrained [1]
. (Moreover when
bank reserves are being added to, it is not even clear
why the deficit should be "financed largely by
monetisation" as the PMEAC report assumes rather
arbitrarily). On the other hand suppose the entire
deficit is completely monetised. If the value of the
Keynesian multiplier (at unchanged interest rates) is
higher than the value of the money multiplier times
the income velocity of circulation of money (also at
unchanged interest rates), there would be an excess
demand for money that would push up the interest
rates, even though the fiscal deficit had been
entirely monetised! In other words the proposition
that when the fiscal deficit is monetised it affects
not the interest rates but only prices relative to
money wages is doubly wrong: there is no necessary
reason why it should at all affect prices, and there
is no necessary reason why it should not at all affect
the interest rates.
Now consider the second case, where there is no
monetisation. Even if the deficit is financed entirely
by "borrowing in the domestic financial market", it
need not raise the interest rate at all if banks had
excess reserves to start with. On the other hand if
the fiscal deficit so financed occurs in a real
economy which is supply-constrained to start with,
then it raises prices in terms of the wage-unit,
thereby imposing an inflationary squeeze on the poor.
Thus the PMEAC's second case which is supposed to show
that a fiscal deficit financed by market borrowing as
opposed to monetisation causes a rise in interest
rates rather than in prices in terms of the wage-unit
is also doubly wrong: there is no necessary reason why
it should at all affect the interest rates, and there
is no necessary reason why it should not at all affect
prices.
There are two quite distinct errors underlying the
argument of the PMEAC report. First, as simple IS-LM
analysis would show, it is not how the fiscal deficit
is financed that matters but the state of ex-ante
excess demand in the goods and the money markets with
which we start and how these are affected by the
fiscal deficit. Second, again as simple IS-LM analysis
would show, a rise in the fiscal deficit would raise
prices in wage units (whether or not it raises
interest rates) only if the economy is
supply-constrained to start with, and would raise
interest rates (whether or not it raises prices in
wage-units) only if bank credit is supply-constrained
to start with. This latter situation in turn cannot
arise if banks have excess reserves (for a given stock
of reserve money), or, alternatively, if the stock of
reserve money itself can adjust to the demand for it.
Thus the argument of the PMEAC report must necessarily
be assuming (though this is nowhere explicitly stated)
both that the real economy is supply-constrained and
that bank credit is supply-constrained. Both these
assumptions are palpably wrong in the context of the
Indian economy today. Let us see how.
III
Let us take bank credit first. In any situation where
banks hold a larger amount of government securities
than required under the SLR obligation, they can
always off- load a portion of these securities to the
RBI, if not directly then at any rate at the margin by
not picking up fresh government debt (which ipso facto
would then devolve upon the RBI in its role as the
underwriter of this debt). It follows that whenever
banks hold excess government securities, since these
can be traded for reserve money but are not, the
credit market must be a buyers' market, i.e. there
must be a shortage of demand for credit from
worthwhile borrowers. Credit cannot be
supply-constrained in such a situation.
This is precisely the case in India today. Indeed the
Economic Survey 2000-01 states this quite clearly:
"The position changed with the inflows under IMDs in
November 2000, which led to a sharp increase in the
RBI's net foreign currency assets. The resultant
generation of liquidity facilitated a sharp reduction
in RBI's net domestic assets by enabling the RBI to
off-load from its portfolio a significant portion of
Central government dated securities to the market"
(p.55). If credit had been supply-constrained in the
economy, then the "market" which includes the banking
system would never have moved into government
securities.
One remark of the PMEAC may be construed as a
counter-argument to what has just been said, but that
remark itself constitutes yet another logical
contradiction in the PMEAC's argument. The PMEAC
report says: "In recent years the government has been
borrowing at around 11 percent when inflation averaged
around 5 percent. This implies real interest rates of
6 percent for government borrowing, which means that
private sector financing has to be at real interest
rates of 8 percent or so for the best corporates and
correspondingly higher for others. With such high real
interest rates, private investment is bound to be
choked off, which is exactly what has happened." This
argument would appear to contradict my argument that
"excess holding" of government securities by banks can
occur only when credit is demand-constrained, since it
believes that this "excess holding" is because of the
attractiveness of government securities.
This argument of the PMEAC however is logically faulty
for two reasons: first, a 6 percent real rate of
interest on government securities can correspondingly
increase the interest rate on private securities only
under certain circumstances. An obvious one is if the
supply of government securities is infinitely elastic
at this rate. If the supply is only a finite amount,
then after this amount has been picked up, banks
having additional resources will start picking up
private securities at 6 percent or even lower real
rates (as long as they cover "marginal cost"). A 8
percent floor real rate for private securities can
operate only if banks' resources are limited relative
to the supply of government securities. But if that
were the case then the Reserve Bank (whose Governor is
a member of the PMEAC) should be deemed to have
committed a great disservice to the nation by
offloading "from its portfolio a significant portion
of Central government dated securities to the market."
The RBI cannot gratuitously increase the stock of
government securities in the market and then complain
that there are too many government securities in the
market! Attributing sense to the RBI must therefore
lead to the conclusion that it offloaded securities
because banks had extra resources owing to
insufficient demand for credit from worthwhile
borrowers. In other words, banks' holding of excess
government securities suggests that credit is not
supply-constrained.
Secondly, the interest rate comparison in the PMEAC
report is wrong, as the following example will show.
Suppose for simplicity that banks have only three
assets, cash, government securities, and loans to
commercial enterprises, and suppose they are required
to maintain 10 percent of their assets as cash and 25
percent as government securities. Suppose also, to
start with, that they hold Rs.10 of cash reserves,
Rs.29 of government securities, and Rs.61 of credit,
i.e. they are maintaining the cash-reserve ratio but
have "excess holding" of government securities. Then
by selling Re.1 of government securities to the RBI,
they can, collectively, expand their assets to Rs.11
of cash, Rs.28 of government securities, and Rs.71 of
credit, provided there is plentiful demand for credit.
If the number of banks is small and profit prospects
significant,they would indeed be expected to
co-operate to realise these prospects. Hence if r
denotes the real interest rate on government
securities and r' the rate on credit, then banks in
the above example would get rid of excess holding of
securities if 10 times r' exceeds r. More generally,
if the cash-reserve ratio is denoted by c, banks would
never hold excess government securities as long as
r'/c exceeds r. The real comparison to make in other
words is not between r' and r, as the PMEAC does, but
between r'/c and r, where the former must win. It
follows then that "excess holding" of government
securities will never be resorted to if adequate
credit demand is forthcoming.
The fact that the banking system in India has been
holding excess government securities implies then that
credit has not been supply-constrained, in which case
one of the assumptions underlying the PMEAC argument
collapses. The other assumption, namely that the real
economy is supply-constrained, is even more palpably
wrong. When the country has 45 million tonnes of
foodgrain stocks, when industrial growth is slowing
down, when the existence of a demand constraint over
vast sectors of Indian industry is recognised even by
the Economic Survey, it is indeed sad to see that the
group of highly distinguished economists which
constitutes the PMEAC has put forward an argument
which assumes Keynesian full employment!
Since our system is demand-constrained both in credit
and commodity markets, the basic assumptions of the
PMEAC report break down. Thus, no matter which of its
alternative versions we consider, the proposition that
the real interest rate is high because of the high
levels of fiscal deficits is erroneous: the theory it
invokes for itself is in each case untenable; and the
conditions under which it might hold empirically, if
inserted within a tenable theory, are far removed from
those that are actually obtaining.
IV
But if the high real rates
of interest prevailing in the economy have nothing to
do with the level of the fiscal deficit, then what
does account for them? We have to bring in the
stock-decisions here, i.e. the factors underlying the
stock-equilibrium. [2]
We also have to
take cognisance of the fact that the 1990s have seen
an opening up of the economy to freer capital flows,
including in particular financial flows, from and to
the rest of the world.
In a world in which finance is free to move, if the
identities of the countries did not matter at all, the
rates of return would be equalised across all
countries. In fact this was the proposition that
underlay the Mundell-Fleming model. But identities of
countries do matter: finance whether originating in
the first or the third world would, if the rates of
return were identical, rather move to the first world,
which constitutes the home base of capitalism, than
stay on in the third world where the elements of risk
and uncertainty are much greater from its point of
view. Consequently, in a world with free mobility of
finance, the tendency would be for the rate of return
to finance to be higher in absolute terms in the third
world countries than in the first world in order to
prevent its flight, which means that the real rate of
interest, as a representative rate of return, would
generally tend to be higher in the former than in the
latter. Since the real rate of interest was
exceedingly low, even close to zero in several third
world countries, including India, in the period before
"liberalisation", this also necessarily entails an
increase in the average real rate of interest in the
post-"liberalisation" as compared to the pre-"liberalisation"
years. To be sure, since the real rate is the
difference between two magnitudes, in particular
periods, with sudden changes for instance in the
inflation rate, it may move up or down sharply. The
point however is that "liberalisation", in particular
the opening up of the economy to freer movements of
globalised finance (even when the currency is not
fully convertible), pushes the country into a real
interest regime that is higher compared to what
prevails in the metropolis, and higher compared to its
own past.
This is exactly what has happened in India where the
real interest rate in the 1990s have been higher on
average than in the metropolis and higher on average
than in the past. And the same story can be read in
the case of virtually every third world country.
Now, it is quite possible that if a third world
country increases its fiscal deficit, then
international finance, which does not like any form of
State activism except that which promotes its own
interest, would consider this a dangerous development,
and start moving out of the country; and in such a
case it may have to be enticed to stay through the
offer of an even higher real rate of interest. The
size of the fiscal deficit in other words may have a
bearing on the real rate of interest, not because of
any sound economic reasons but solely owing to the
caprices of international finance capital. But to
argue for a reduction in the size of the fiscal
deficit on these grounds, as a means of appeasing
international finance capital, is both unsound and
obnoxious.
It is unsound because, no matter what the size of the
fiscal deficit, a certain minimum real rate of
interest which itself is quite high would necessarily
have to prevail in a third world economy open to
financial flows. It is significant for example that
Thailand which on the eve of its financial crisis in
1997 had a fiscal surplus equal to 3 percent of its
GDP had nonetheless a 10 percent real rate of
interest.
The argument is obnoxious because it tailors economic
policy not to the needs of the people but to the
caprices of international finance. Just as the fact
that international finance may not like a particular
Prime Minister, or a particular political Party in
power, should not be an argument for jettisoning that
person or Party if they enjoy popular support,
likewise the fact that it dislikes fiscal deficits
should not be an argument for eschewing the latter if
there is no sound economic case against them. On the
contrary the prejudice of international finance in all
such cases has to be dealt with by circumscribing its
freedom of movement rather than by circumscribing the
country's freedom to pursue economic policies of its
choice.
It follows from what has been argued above that the
high fiscal deficit is not the cause but the result of
the high real rate of interest, which ceteris paribus
increases the interest payment burden of the State.
Since the high real rate is itself a necessary
accompaniment of "liberalisation", the fiscal deficit
in turn can be traced to the process of "liberalisation"
itself. To be sure India had a fiscal crisis before
the policy of "liberalisation" began, but this fiscal
crisis has got accentuated by the process of "liberalisation",
and the fact that the fiscal deficit continues to be
high despite significant expenditure compression is a
reflection of this accentuation.
There are in fact two distinct ways in which "liberalisation"
has contributed to this accentuation. One, as already
mentioned, is the rise in interest rates that must
occur as a consequence of freer financial flows. The
other is the reduction in tax-GDP ratio which
inevitably occurs in a "liberalised" economy. Since
trade "liberalisation" involves reducing customs
duties, and since an economy that is reducing customs
duties can scarcely increase excise duties (as that
would entail gratuitous de-industrialisation) the
capacity of such an economy to raise revenues through
indirect taxes gets impaired. Likewise since
attracting foreign capital involves taxing it as
lightly as other wooing economies, and inter se equity
implies that the taxing of domestic capital can not be
too far out of line with that of foreign capital, and
also that personal income taxation cannot be too far
out of line with corporate income taxation, the
capacity to garner revenues through direct taxes gets
impaired. A reduction in the tax-GDP ratio, such as
has occurred in India in the 1990s, is the inevitable
sequel. This fact and the rise in the State's interest
payments obligation, both fall-outs of "liberalisation",
underlie the accentuation of the pre-existing fiscal
crisis, which results in some mix of expenditure
compression and an even larger profile of State debt
(which makes things even worse over time). Expenditure
compression in turn whittles down anti-poverty
programmes (which despite all "leakages" have some
impact by way of reducing poverty, especially in rural
areas), reduces social expenditure as well as
investment in infrastructure, and unleashes recession
and stagnation in major commodity-producing sectors.
The fallacy in the thinking of several well-meaning
economists who want both "liberalisation" and
greater social expenditure lies precisely in their
failure to see this fact, namely that expenditure
compression, including on social sectors, is an
inevitable fall-out of "liberalisation". The fallacy in the government's
position lies in mistaking the consequence for the
cause, in identifying what is the consequence of "liberalisation"
as the cause for its lack of success. One particular
example of this inverted reasoning is to see the high
interest rates as the consequence of the fiscal
deficit, while in fact they are a cause of it.
This reasoning however leads to further expenditure
compression, a further compounding of the crisis
engulfing the infrastructure and social sectors, and a
further perpetuation of recessionary conditions.
Curtailing the fiscal deficit brings little relief by
way of a reduction in interest rates, and hence
scarcely any stimulus to aggregate demand via this
avenue; on the other hand the cuts in expenditures,
especially investment and social expenditures, which
are undertaken for achieving this curtailment in the
fiscal deficit, have a demand depressing effect. The
obsession with cutting the fiscal deficit in a
demand-constrained system represents quintessential
economic unwisdom.
V
The most bizarre example of
this unwisdom relates to the foodgrain economy: in a
country of starving millions over 45 million tonnes of
foodgrain stocks are held which the government does
not know what to do with, and is even exporting abroad
at prices charged to the BPL population, i.e. prices
less than those charged in the domestic market. The
high carrying costs of these stocks (including
interest costs) are the principal reason behind the
inflated the food subsidy bill. The government's
misguided effort to curb food subsidy by increasing
PDS prices, such as the one undertaken in last year's
budget, has the apparently paradoxical effect of not
doing so: the higher prices simply lead to lower
offtake which keeps the foodgrain stocks larger than
before and hence their carrying cost increases. As a
result the total food subsidy remains as large as
before while its composition changes with a higher
share going for holding costs and a lower share to the
consumer.
Some have even suggested a dismantling of the entire
PDS, on the grounds that this would bring down the
foodgrains price. But while that may be true today,
and may even get rid of the existing unwanted stocks,
the suggestion is extraordinarily short-sighted: when
market prices rise at some future date, the poor would
be without any protection in the absence of the PDS.
The whole point of the system of
procurement-cum-public distribution that has prevailed
in the country for the last three and a half decades
has been to keep down the amplitude of price
fluctuations both for producers and for consumers,
which would have otherwise been extremely large in the
free market, and which is actually extremely large in
the world market. The system has been remarkably
successful in meeting this objective. If the level of
the food price is high in the PDS, and there is an
inadequate lifting of stocks, then the solution lies
in putting grater purchasing power in the hands of the
poor, so that they can lift larger stocks, rather than
in dismantling the system altogether. In other words a
simple solution exists to the problem of surplus
foodstocks, namely to expand the food-for-work
programme. This would get rid of the stocks by
enabling the poor to consume more food; and if
properly conceived could even result in the creation
of rural infrastructure and community assets.
This however is not on the government's agenda, since
it would raise the size of the fiscal deficit. This
particular objection to an enlarged employment
programme is doubly erroneous: first, in a
demand-constrained system, a rise in State expenditure
on the poor, even if financed by a fiscal deficit,
should be welcome anyway. (If international finance
disapproves of it and expresses this disapproval
through capital outflows, then that constitutes an
argument for controlling its unrestricted movement
rather than for restricting such expenditure).
Secondly, a substantial part of this expenditure which
would flow back to the FCI (or to other State-owned
units) does not even constitute fiscal deficit, since
it leads to no increase in the net indebtedness of the
State. Yet, so great is the current obsession with
restricting the fiscal deficit that the government is
willing to dismantle the PDS rather than undertake a
larger employment-generation programme.
This effectively is what the current budget has
announced, notwithstanding all claims to the contrary.
What appears at first sight as a mere transfer of the
responsibility for procuring and distributing
foodgrains from the central government to the state
governments, actually amounts to a blow against the
entire system for at least two reasons. First, any
replication of the problem of unsold stocks, which
currently plagues the system as it is run by the
Centre, at the level of the states, would place the
latter in a far worse position to take corrective
measures. This is because the Centre has passed the
burden of the fiscal crisis down to the level of the
state governments to a point where it is even more
acute for them than for the Centre. Secondly, states
which are far removed from the centres of procurement
will have to pay much more for food even if they
continue a system of public distribution, since the
Central government will no longer provide them with
food, and since the cash subsidy it will give would
only cover the BPL population. Under these
circumstances the maintenance of a system where both
producers and consumers are offered a degree of
insulation from extreme price fluctuations will become
well-nigh impossible. The virtual dismantling of the
PDS, instead of supplementing it with a food-for-work
programme, is perhaps the most disastrous fall-out of
the obsession with the fiscal deficit, which, as Joan
Robinson would have put it, is part of the "humbug of
finance".
[1]
Of course even in a demand-constrained system an
increase in aggregate demand, while generating larger
employment and output, might cause some increase in
the price in terms of the wage-unit, owing to
(possibly) increasing marginal costs. But this surely
is not what the PMEAC is referring to, for otherwise
even getting out of a slump would be dubbed
"anti-poor". Its notion of "inflation" clearly refers
to a state of affairs where it is only price
adjustments that occur.
[2]
In fact in view of our argument above that credit has
not been supply-constrained, the level of the interest
rate can be explained solely in terms of stock
decisions.