I have chosen
as the title of my lecture a phrase used by Professor Joan Robinson, who,
in her book Economic Philosophy,
talks of "the humbug of finance which Keynes had destroyed". What she means
by the phrase "the humbug of finance" is the view held by British
finance capital, based in the City of London, in the late twenties, and
propagated by the British Treasury (because of which this view came to be
known as the "Treasury View") that in all circumstances the government's
balancing its expenditure with its income, i.e. not resorting to any fiscal
deficit, is the most desirable policy for an economy. The British colonial
government in India, it may be recalled, had used precisely this argument
for pursuing deflationary policies even during the years of the Great Depression
because of the fall in its tax revenue. This had succeeded in worsening
the impact of the Depression on our economy,
had thwarted the industrialisation prospects which the policy of protection
of the inter-war period had opened up,
and had resulted in a wholesale running down of the economy's infrastructure.
This view in short was pervasive in the pre-Keynesian era. A slight variation
of this view is that the fiscal deficit must under all circumstances never
be allowed to exceed a certain small limit.
The theoretical articulation of the Treasury view was contained
in a White Paper of the British Treasury in 1929, called "Memorandum
On Certain Proposals Relating to Unemployment", and written in response
to Lloyd George's suggestion that Britain should undertake public works
for reducing unemployment which at that time stood at 10 percent (it was
to reach 20 percent later). The White Paper argued that in any economy there
is at any time only a certain pool of savings, and that if more of it is
used for home investment then less becomes available for foreign investment,
or if more of it is used for public works financed by government borrowing,
then less is left over for private investment and foreign investment. It
follows then that public works can never increase total employment in an
economy since the increase in employment brought about by public works would
be exactly counterbalanced by the reduction in employment arising from reduced
private and foreign investment.
The fallacy of this argument was exposed by a young Cambridge
economist and pupil of Keynes, Richard Kahn, in a classic paper published
in 1931.
The argument was simple: total savings in an economy depend, among other
things, on its total income. There is therefore no fixed pool of savings,
unless we assume that income cannot be augmented, i.e. the economy is already
at full employment, in which case the need for public works does not arise.
The Treasury View in other words was arguing against proposals for reducing
unemployment on the basis of a theory that implicitly assumed that unemployment
did not exist at all. In an economy in which there is unemployment, in the
sense of resources lying idle owing to lack of aggregate demand, if investment
increases then these resources start getting used up directly and indirectly,
through various rounds of the "multiplier". As a result, income
rises and so do savings. Indeed, Kahn showed, the whole process of increase
in income and employment would go on and on, until an amount of savings
had been generated which exactly equalled the increase in home and foreign
investment. Far from there being a predetermined pool of savings above which
investment cannot increase, it is the total investment that determines the
total savings: the direction of causation in other words is precisely the
opposite of what pre-Keynesian theory believed. A corollary of Kahn's theorem
was that if the government expanded public works for generating employment
and financed these by borrowing, i.e. by enlarging the fiscal deficit, then
an exactly equivalent amount of savings would accrue in private hands. A
fiscal deficit in other words finances itself.
The argument advanced by Kahn in 1931 was central to Keynes'
opus The General Theory of Employment,
Interest and Money published in 1936. Keynes argued in a similar manner
that in a situation of "involuntary unemployment", or "demand
constraint", the government can
enlarge employment and output by increasing its fiscal deficit; far from
there being any adverse effects of this on any other stream of expenditure,
such government action in fact would stimulate the total expenditure from
these other streams via the "multiplier", and not even generate
any significant inflationary pressures. Moreover, since the government can successfully pursue such a policy,
it must do so, because, as Keynes
put it, "it is certain that the world will not much longer tolerate
the unemployment which, apart from brief intervals of excitement, is associated
-- and, in my opinion, inevitably associated -- with present day capitalistic
individualism."
Even if the government used the fiscal deficit for no worthier purpose than
"to dig holes in the ground", that is still preferable to letting
unemployment persist, since "'to dig holes in the ground' paid for
out of savings, will increase, not only employment, but the real national
dividend of useful goods and services"
(again because of the "multiplier"). To argue against the mitigation
to human suffering that an increased fiscal deficit can provide is therefore
bad theory, the sheer "humbug of finance".
The reason for my reviving this old and familiar discussion is
that today in India we are once again witnessing the parading as wisdom
of this "humbug of finance", and there is even large-scale acceptance
of this "humbug" as wisdom. What is more, the "humbug"
that is being paraded as wisdom in our country is even more of "humbug"
than what Kahn and Keynes had attacked. In other words the "humbug
of finance" that we are being subjected to even "out-humbugs"
the "humbug of finance" that the British Treasury was purveying
during the Depression of the late twenties. Let me explain this last point
first.
I
There were no public sector enterprises in Britain during the
late-twenties. The government sector's transactions therefore were co-terminus
with budgetary transactions, so that the term fiscal deficit corresponded
to the deficit of the government sector. This deficit had necessarily to
match, as an algebraic truism, the surplus of the rest of the world vis-à-vis
the British economy plus the surplus
of the British private sector. An increase in the fiscal deficit, assuming
foreign transactions were unaffected, would necessarily correspond to an
equivalent increase in the private sector's surplus of income over expenditure.
What Keynesian theory argued is that an increase in the fiscal deficit in
a demand-constrained system would cause an equivalent increase in private
surplus (and hence finance itself) through an increase in the private sector's
income (via larger employment and output through the demand stimulus
obtained from the government) rather than through a reduction in private expenditure, in particular
investment expenditure, which the Treasury View with its fantastic notion
of a savings pool had claimed. As the government deficit goes up by Rs.100,
employment, output and incomes go up until private savings have gone up
by Rs.100 (assuming private investment remains unchanged), i.e. an extra
Rs.100 of wealth has been put into private hands, which is held directly
or indirectly in the form of claims on government.
Now, even though the use of fiscal deficit for increasing employment
is perfectly legitimate, one may have reservations about this particular mode of raising employment,
for three reasons: first, a fiscal deficit-financed expansion in activity,
as just mentioned, does accentuate wealth inequalities compared to an equivalent
tax-financed expansion of activity. In a society wishing to keep wealth
inequalities in check, it is better to finance government expenditure by
taxing capitalists than by borrowing from them. Secondly, there may be problems
about knowing how much fiscal deficit is needed to get to "full employment"
(which in a capitalist economy would never mean employment for everybody
willing to work, but would only entail lowering unemployment to that level
of the reserve army which is the minimum necessary for the avoidance of
cumulative price instability). Suppose for instance that the owners of wealth
increase their consumption as their wealth increases but with a time-lag.
Then if, say, with Rs.100 of fiscal deficit the economy gets pushed to full
employment before private consumption has responded to the increased wealth,
then once it begins to respond, Rs.100 of fiscal deficit would turn out
in retrospect to have been too large, since now there would be too much
demand. Thirdly, even if private wealth has no effect on private consumption,
if the economy gets taken to full employment through a fiscal deficit-financed
expansion in activity, then at full employment there would be a large overhang
of private wealth in liquid form (as direct or indirect claims upon government)
and these, when resources are being fully utilised, can give rise to speculation-engendered
inflation.
None of the above considerations justify the "humbug of
finance". What they say is that while an increase in the fiscal deficit
can increase employment, and should be
used for doing so if necessary, there are other
ways of increasing employment, through tax-financed increases in government
expenditure for example, which might be even better for the purpose. Of
course if the latter cannot be implemented easily then fiscal deficit should
be resorted to rather than keeping unemployment going.
Even these residual objections to fiscal deficit however vanish
when the result of the fiscal deficit is to increase not private savings and wealth but those of public sector
enterprises. When this happens, there is in effect no increase in the
government sector's deficit. What appears as an increase in the fiscal deficit
is counterbalanced by a surplus in the rest of the government sector not
reflected in the budget, so that the appearance of a fiscal deficit is entirely
on account of the convention of making the budget reflect only a part of
the government sector's transactions; it
has no economic significance. To object to an increase in the fiscal
deficit in such a situation is even more theoretically illegitimate than
to do so in a situation where there is no public sector. If the objection
even in the latter case is the sheer "humbug of finance", then
in the former case the "humbug" is, if anything, compounded several-fold.
And yet in India there is an objection to an increase in the fiscal deficit
even when the consequences of such an increase would accrue as larger surpluses
to the public sector, which is why the "humbug of finance" being
purveyed in our country today "out-humbugs" the "humbug"
attacked by Kahn and Keynes. I shall give three examples of such "supreme
humbug" (if I may call it so).
II
At this moment there are over 32 million tonnes of foodgrain
stocks in the economy. Since 20 million tonnes of foodgrain stocks are considered
adequate by the government (for this time of the year) as buffer-cum-operational
stocks, it follows that at least 12 million tonnes of surplus stocks are
lying idle with the Food Corporation of India. The existence of idle stocks
of foodgrains in a country afflicted by large-scale poverty and malnutrition,
is so palpably absurd that there have been proposals from time to time within
the government itself to get rid of these stocks by putting purchasing power
in the hands of the rural poor through a massive expansion in employment-generation
schemes.
Such an expansion of employment generation schemes will kill
several birds with one stone. First, it will bring down unemployment and
poverty; secondly it will get rid of the idle stocks which are currently
hanging like a mill-stone round the Food Corporation of India's neck; thirdly,
if such employment-generation schemes are properly conceived, then they
can add to social overhead capital in rural India and improve the quality
of life, or augment productive investment and contribute towards a larger
output in the future: since the decade of the nineties has seen a decline
in per capita foodgrain output in the country, the first decade since independence
to have done so, any addition to productive investment effected in this
manner, would be quite crucial. It follows, given all these possibilities,
that allowing idle foodgrain stocks to continue is extremely irrational;
it represents criminal waste in a poor economy like ours.
Why is it then that these foodgrain stocks are not being used
for employment-generation programmes? The answer is that such expenditure
will increase the fiscal deficit! All suggestions, even those emanating
from within the government itself, for reducing idle stocks through enlarging
employment-generation programmes have been turned down on these grounds.
Now, this is "supreme humbug". Let us assume, for simplicity,
that employment generation programmes require only labour and that labour
spends its wages only on foodgrains. If Rs.100 are spent on employment generation
through an increase in government borrowing (i.e. the fiscal deficit rises
by Rs.100), then these Rs.100 would be spent on foodgrains and hence (ignoring
minor complications like transport costs) the FCI's stocks would go down
by Rs.100. The FCI can then repay Rs.100 to the banks from whom it has taken
credit for stock-holding. It follows that as the government borrowing increases
by Rs.100 for financing employment-generation programmes, it reduces by
Rs.100 as a consequence of such programmes, so that the net government indebtedness does not change. What appears
as an increase in the fiscal deficit in this case is no actual increase:
it is only a consequence of the fact that FCI transactions do not figure
in the budget as a matter of convention
(indeed they used to figure in the budget until the early seventies). And
if there is no actual increase in the fiscal deficit, but only an apparent
one, then it cannot conceivably have
even the adverse consequences that the protagonists of financial orthodoxy
associate with larger fiscal deficits. If nonetheless there is opposition
to such a seeming increase in the fiscal deficit, then what else can one
call it but the "supreme humbug of finance"?
To be sure, I assumed above that the employment-generation schemes
required only labour and that labour demanded only foodgrains. But dropping
these assumptions only means that in addition to foodgrains there would
be some extra demand for non-food wage goods and for material inputs for
the employment programmes. Given the fact however that industry too has
been afflicted by a demand constraint of late, this would only mean that
Rs.100 of spending on employment-generation would clear less than Rs.100
of foodgrain stocks, while creating extra demand for industrial goods, and
bringing forth lager industrial output, from the remainder, which can scarcely
be frowned upon. True, in this case not all of Rs.100 would accrue back
to the government via the FCI; a part would materialise as private savings
and hence would entail an increase in the government's net indebtedness.
But objecting to this in a demand-constrained system is theoretically illegitimate:
it would still qualify, on Keynes-Kahn grounds, as "the humbug of finance".
The purveyors of humbug in this particular case often fall back
on a second line of defence. This states that the accumulation of surplus
foodgrain stocks is only a temporary phenomenon; if one enlarges employment-generation
(poverty-reduction) programmes now because of this temporary surplus, then,
once the surplus is used up, the poor would be back to square one. Enlarging
such programmes, which have got to be sustained, purely on the strength
of a temporary foodgrain surplus, would be irrational.
There are two immediate rejoinders one can make to this argument.
First, if employment-generation programmes are carefully planned, then they
can result in sustainable increases in foodgrain output, in which case the
temporary surplus can become the means of obtaining a permanent surplus
(though not necessarily of the same order) that can effect a permanent reduction
in poverty. Secondly, even if this were not the case and that the temporary
surplus can only bring temporary relief, what is wrong with temporary relief?
Beyond these however there is a more important point. Apart from
a brief interlude in 1992 and 1993 when the central cereal stocks, especially
wheat stocks, fell below the prescribed "norm" and necessitated
some imports, the level of these stocks has been well above the "norm"
throughout the 1990s. We are in
other words not experiencing any temporary surplus, but a more or less permanent
glut, and that too at a time when the per capita foodgrain output has shown
a declining trend, and the rural poverty ratio an increasing trend. The
economy has been transformed into a demand-constrained one, and it is this
context rather than any temporary foodgrain surplus which lends urgency
to the plea for an increase in the scale of employment-generation programmes.
It is incredible that in the context of this transformation of
the economy into a demand-constrained one, with the coexistence of huge
foodgrain stocks, large unutilised industrial capacity, reasonable foreign
exchange reserves (we shall discuss their adequacy later) and growing rural
poverty, the Finance Minister actually claims that reducing the fiscal deficit
is the primary task before the government, and that too when the ongoing
inflation rate is a mere 2-3 percent! It is even more incredible that he
gets away with this claim with not a single dissenting voice in the media.
This is indicative of the triumph of the humbug of finance in today's India.
III
My second example is logically analogous to the first one. There
is an almost unanimous view in government and media circles that India needs
foreign capital to develop its power sector. When in response to a High
Court ruling on a Public Interest Litigation recently, Cogentrix announced
that it would pull out of its proposed power project in Karnataka, it began
to be placated with unprecedented ardour. The Supreme Court was pressurised
into overturning the High Court verdict, the Central government came up
with counter-guarantees that Cogentrix, sensing its chance, started demanding,
and the President of Assocham wanted curbs on Public Interest Litigations
altogether! The clear impression
was given that the heavens would fall if Cogentrix pulled out. But the question
remains unanswered: why do we need Cogentrix (or Enron), and that too when
the domestic power equipment producer, BHEL, has large unutilised capacity
owing to lack of orders, when the technology of putting up power plants
is well-known to us, and when it is also well-known that the foreign producers
inflate their capital costs (owing to the system of guaranteed rates of
return) and produce power at a higher cost per unit than can be done with
Indian equipment.
The answer cannot be that they bring foreign exchange, since
the foreign exchange they bring is to cover the purchase of equipment which
they import; if we did not use their equipment we would not need this foreign
exchange in the first place. The only possible answer can therefore be that
they bring finance, that if they
were not entrusted with the task then the government would have to finance
these power projects from its budgetary resources, which typically would
mean a larger fiscal deficit. In short, power projects are being entrusted
to Multinational Corporations in order to avoid a larger fiscal deficit.
This once again is an example of what I have called the "supreme humbug
of finance" which is even more of "humbug" than what Kahn
and Keynes had demolished.
Suppose the government borrows Rs.100 and spends the sum on a
power project. Suppose for simplicity that the only cost of a power project
is equipment cost. Then these Rs.100 would accrue as sales revenue to BHEL,
a public sector undertaking. Suppose again for simplicity that the bulk
of the cost of power equipment production is in the nature of fixed costs,
then these Rs.100 would accrue to BHEL as operating surplus which would
be saved during the period, in the form, say, of bank deposits. Now, even
though the fiscal deficit appears to have gone up by Rs.100, the net indebtedness
of the government has not increased at all: the government on its budgetary
account has borrowed Rs.100, but holds these Rs.100 in the form of bank
deposits of a public sector undertaking. For the government as a whole the
liabilities and the assets have gone up identically, by Rs.100, leaving
its net indebtedness unchanged. The higher fiscal deficit therefore is only
apparent, a consequence of the convention that the transactions of public
sector undertakings are not part of the budgetary transactions. Even by
the logic of the votaries of financial orthodoxy therefore the adverse consequences
that are supposed by them to follow from higher fiscal deficits should not
be visited upon the economy in this instance.
No doubt, our simplifying assumptions would not hold in practice,
necessitating some increase in government indebtedness, though again, in
so far as through the different "multiplier" rounds following
the initial government expenditure of Rs.100, the profits, and hence savings,
of other public sector enterprises also go up, the net indebtedness of the
government would, to that extent, be kept down. Since the different public
sector enterprises in India provide inputs to one another (not to mention
the fact that FCI foodgrains stock-decumulation provides the additional
food demanded by workers when the wage bill goes up), an increase of Rs.100
in power sector investment would largely come back as additional savings
of public sector enterprises without any increase in net indebtedness. In
short, as long as unutilised capacity owing to deficient
demand exists in the power equipment and its feeder units belonging to the
public sector, to talk of the government's experiencing a shortage of finance
for power investment is "supreme humbug". Even if some of
these feeder units are in the private sector, as long as they have unutilised
capacity, power investment financed by a fiscal deficit, even though it
would raise the government's net indebtedness, would still make perfect
sense on the Kahn-Keynes grounds. The opposition to it constitutes the "humbug
of finance".
The point here is not
whether a larger fiscal deficit is the best way of financing power investment.
Nor am I suggesting that all of India's immediate power needs can be met
through such financing alone.
The point being made here is altogether different and can be summed up as
follows: first, in a situation of demand constraint, financing investment
through a fiscal deficit is perfectly legitimate even when the government's
net indebtedness goes up as a result of it; secondly, very often the government's
indebtedness does not even go up since the multiplier effects are all within
the public sector itself; thirdly, to invite Multinational Corporations
desperately for investment in the power sector, on the plea of a shortage
of finance, in a situation of demand constraint for power equipment and
feeder units, is to be fooled by the "humbug of finance"; fourthly,
to do so when these demand-constrained equipment and feeder units are all
in the government-owned sector itself is to be taken in by the "supreme
humbug of finance". Unfortunately this last case is what fits the Indian
government's current policy in the power sector.
IV
My last example is slightly different in nature. It relates to
the practice followed in recent years of treating the proceeds from the
sale of public sector enterprises' equity as being analogous to revenue,
and hence using such sales proceeds to "bridge" the fiscal deficit.
This practice, based on a confusion between stocks and flows, is manifestly
unsound.
Consider an example: suppose the government has a fiscal deficit
of Rs.100. This must generate private savings worth Rs.100 which would be
held in the form, directly or indirectly, of claims upon the government.
In a situation of demand-constraint, these savings are generated through
an increase in output, employment and incomes. But if the economy is supply-constrained,
then these savings would be generated through an inflationary squeeze on
real wages. Hence the fiscal deficit can be objected to on the grounds that
it would cause inflation (or equivalently, balance of payments problems)
by creating excess demand, if the economy happens to be supply-constrained.
Now, if the government raises Rs.100 through disinvestment of public sector
equity, then, unless the buyers of
this equity finance this purchase by reducing their own flow expenditures
(and there is no theoretical reason why they should do so), there would be no reduction in excess
demand compared to when there was no disinvestment. The inflationary effects
of the fiscal deficit would be exactly the same whether it is met by borrowing
or through disinvestment. The only difference would be that instead of holding
claims upon the government as in the first case, the private savers would
be holding titles to actual government assets in the second case.
Thus the argument one frequently encounters, namely that the
government should sell off some public sector enterprises and use the proceeds
for increasing social expenditures, is simply erroneous: the macroeconomic
consequences of doing this would be exactly analogous to what would happen
if the government increased social expenditure merely through deficit financing.
There is a variation of this argument which is equally erroneous.
This states that the government should use the proceeds from the sale of
public sector enterprises for retiring public debt, in which case its interest
payment obligations will go down and it can spend more on social sectors.
Suppose the government sells Rs.100 of public sector equity and retires
public debt of an equal amount. If the interest rate it had to pay on this
debt was 10 percent, then it would be saving Rs.10 per annum from then onwards
on interest payments and can therefore spend Rs.10 more per annum on social
sectors. But the public sector enterprise whose equity is being sold would
have also earned some returns every year. The argument for disinvestment
would make sense only if these returns were less than Rs.10 per annum. But if they were less than Rs.10 per annum, then why should any private
agent pay Rs.100 for them? With returns less than Rs.10 per annum, their
present value, at the same rate of discount as the interest rate on public
debt, would be less than Rs.100. It follows that unless the private buyers
employ a lower rate of interest for discounting the returns, on the public
enterprise they purchase, than the rate of interest on public debt, selling
off public enterprises can never improve
the government's ability to spend. Since there is absolutely no reason
why their discount rate should be lower than the interest rate on public
debt (in fact it would be invariably much higher since the rate of interest
at which they borrow from banks is generally higher), every such disinvestment,
instead of improving the government's spending capacity, actually worsens
it.
It may be argued that while the level of flow demand might remain
unaffected whether the fiscal deficit is met by borrowing or disinvestment,
the difference in private portfolio between these two cases would have important
secondary effects, in so far as claims upon the government, being more liquid,
can exacerbate excess demand-caused inflation, more than the ownership of
government property which would be relatively illiquid. But, first of all,
this is not necessarily true: government equity is no less liquid than government
bonds or term-deposits with banks. Secondly, the degree of liquidity of
the private portfolio can acquire relevance only if excess demand-based
inflationary pressures are engendered;
in a demand-constrained system the question of such inflationary pressures
simply does not arise. The belief that fiscal deficits cease to be fiscal
deficits if covered by equity disinvestment is therefore doubly wrong: first,
its premise is wrong (since the economy is demand-constrained), and secondly,
its logic is wrong (since equity is not necessarily less liquid than debt).
This premise however is that of the "humbug of finance".
V
The protagonists of this "humbug of finance", who frown
upon fiscal deficits even when the economy is demand constrained, and even
when the savings generated by the fiscal deficit occur within the public
sector itself (and who believe that selling public sector equity mitigates
the effects of a fiscal deficit), often fall back on two additional arguments.
The first states that State intervention in the economy should be eschewed
because it promotes "inefficiency". This argument too is "humbug",
like the rest of the "humbug of finance". If State intervention
in a situation of demand constraint increases
total output, then calling it "inefficient" is a travesty of the
truth. Propositions such as "State intervention causes inefficiency"
invariably assume comparisons between two situations in both of which all resources are fully employed. These propositions
become completely meaningless, nay absurd, when the non-State intervention
situation is demand-constrained.
The second argument runs as follows: the point is not what a
fiscal deficit is intrinsically (i.e. in a ceteris
paribus sense) capable of doing in a particular situation; the point
in today's context is what foreign capital thinks
it would do. And if foreign capital is suspicious of any increase in the
fiscal deficit, then, even if this suspicion is ill-founded, it would nonetheless
ensure that adverse consequences would follow from an enlarged fiscal deficit,
in the form of capital flight for example. The effect on the balance of
payments in this case would be as real, despite the existence of demand-constraint,
as if the fiscal deficit had impacted on it in a situation of supply constraint.
This argument has some merit, but it needs to be inverted. If
the confidence of foreign capital requires a curb on democracy, then that
is no reason for curbing democracy; if foreign capital has more confidence
when the Prime Minister is an ex-employee of the World Bank, then that is
no reason for limiting the country's choice for the post of Prime Minister
only to that set; likewise if workers agitating for their demands dents
foreign capital's confidence then that is no reason for banning workers'
agitations. In all these cases the better course for society to adopt is
to put curbs on foreign capital rather than dance to its tune.
VI
Two questions inevitably arise: first, if the "humbug of
finance" is mere humbug, then how does one explain its revival more
than half a century after it had been buried? This is a complex question
relating to political economy, a convincing answer to which requires answering
two distinct questions: whose interests does it serve? Have some of the
elements whose interests it serves become stronger in recent years?
The basic objective behind propagating the "humbug of finance"
is to prevent, or roll back, any activity on the part of the State to become
a producer, or an active investor, or a controller of capital. This not
only opens up more space for capital, not only permits its grabbing hold
of State assets at throwaway prices, but ushers in a bout of centralisation
of capital in the crisis that follows State withdrawal. It follows then
that different elements of capital have an uneven interest in embracing
or propounding the "humbug of finance": larger capital has greater
interest than smaller capital, and finance capital has greater interest
than manufacturing capital (which benefits from the expansion of the market
caused by State activity).
This is a general picture. Looking at the matter in the context
of the world as a whole, it follows that international capital generally,
and international finance capital in particular, would be the strongest
votary of the "humbug of finance", especially of inflicting it
on third world countries. The third world State acted after decolonisation
as a bulwark against foreign capital and was used by the domestic bourgeoisie
to strengthen itself at the expense of foreign capital. Rolling back the
third world State, in particular relatively autonomous and powerful third
world States like the Indian State, by imposing the "humbug of finance",
represents therefore a major triumph for international (or more accurately
metropolitan) capital. It is able to achieve this triumph partly because
it has become much stronger owing to the inter-related phenomena of subsidence
in inter-imperialist rivalry, and the ascendancy of a new form of metropolis-dominated
supra-national finance capital.
The second question that inevitably arises is: why should the
domestic bourgeoisie in third world have gone along with the propagation
of the "humbug of finance"? In part it has to do with the unsustainability
of the earlier post-independence trajectory of State-sponsored bourgeois
development: having reached a dead end the big bourgeoisie now feels that
its future lies in linking up as a junior partner of metropolitan capital.
In part, the answer has to do also with the pressures exerted by metropolitan
capital itself whose increase in strength in its new incarnation has already
been referred to. It follows then that the third world bourgeoisie has had
a role reversal. In the new historical conjuncture it can no longer play
the positive role of leading the struggle for emancipation of the national
economy from the control of metropolitan capital.
In this context it becomes absolutely and urgently necessary for
all of us, who are not wedded to the cause of the big bourgeoisie or of
metropolitan capital, to expose the "humbug of finance" which
is being used to justify the decimation of the capital goods sector of the
economy and the useless stock-piling of millions of tonnes of foodgrains
in a country of starving people.