Alternative Perspectives on Panchayati Raj

 
May 8th 2009, Prabhat Patnaik
While decentralization of resources and decision-making to Local Self-Governing Institutions run by elected representatives, which is now built into our Constitution, is almost universally supported, there are at least two distinct perspectives underlying this support. Putting it differently, there are at least two very different philosophical approaches to Panchayati Raj.

One locates Panchayati Raj in the concept of a ''village community''. The village according to this view constitutes a unit around which the life of a particular collectivity of people is organized. This view was given much currency during the colonial period by the British author B. H. Baden-Powell, who described pre-colonial India as being characterized by self-sufficient village communities. Subsequent historical research has found that the pre-colonial villages did not constitute self-sufficient economic units. There was considerable commodity production, i.e. production for the market, of agricultural and other goods, because of which the land revenue paid to the overlord was largely in cash. With the entry of cash into its economy, the village was not just a seller of commodities to towns but also a buyer of urban goods manufactured by artisans. That is, superimposed upon the local-level division of labour within the village (sometimes referred to as the jajmani system) there was also exchange between the town and the village. But even though the village as a self-sufficient economic unit might not have characterized pre-colonial India, the ''village community'' as the basis of organization of social life supposedly did.

Many would argue that notwithstanding the colonial period and the decades of post-colonial development, which carried commodity production forward by leaps and bounds, the village community continues to remain the basic unit of organization of social life in India, and that the panchayati raj institutions give expression to this fact. They constitute a ''governance arrangement'' which is desirable because each tier of ''governance'' corresponds to a particular layer of organization of social life: the Union government corresponds to the organization of the Indian nation; the state governments correspond to the various linguistic nationalities (for notwithstanding the recent tendency to break up large states into smaller ones, the linguistic basis for the formation of states continues to be the guiding principle); and the LSGIs correspond to the villages as the basic micro-level unit of organization of social life.

This first approach therefore sees panchayati raj essentially as a ''governance arrangement'' corresponding to a communitarian village life, and hence as an end in itself. Its commitment is to panchayati raj as such, and not to panchayati raj as a means towards the achievement of some other end. And since any ''governance arrangement'' that vests greater power in the ''village community'', is considered superior and more democratic for being closer to the ''people'', this first approach tends to applaud every increase in the devolution of powers and resources from the state government to LSGIs. Or putting it differently, the degree of devolution of powers and resources from the state government to the LSGIs is sought to be increased as far as possible by those subscribing to this perspective, rather than being kept at some appropriate level, which may be considered ''optimal'' for achieving some desired end.

I disagree with this first approach. The problem with it in my view is that it glosses over a basic fact, namely that the village as the unit of social life has also been the location of intense class and caste oppression. The village community was by no means an idyll; within it there was untouchability, ''unseeability'', and other most revolting forms of discrimination. Progress in our country has to take the form of overturning and destroying this village community and not in preserving and giving expression to it. A modern, progressive, secular and egalitarian outlook does not spring up on the village soil spontaneously; it has to be brought to the village from outside. Panchayati Raj institutions must be so fashioned therefore that this march to a modern democratic and egalitarian society is facilitated, rather than impeded, by them. Decentralization is not an end in itself, but a means towards an end; hence the degree of devolution of resources and powers has to be so determined that this process of social transformation is completed without retrogressions.

This is the second approach, which I share. Panchayati Raj according to this view is neither a mere ''governance arrangement'' nor an end in itself. It is a means of social transformation and derives its legitimacy exclusively from the perspective of how far it facilitates this process of social transformation. If we miss the transformational role of panchayati raj and see it only as a ''governance arrangement'', then we may end up condoning and even accentuating caste and class oppression in the countryside.

It is not widely known that Dr. Ambedkar was extremely lukewarm, even hostile, to the idea of panchayati raj, which he feared would perpetuate the oppression of Dalits. This oppression, he felt, could be broken only with ideas and interventions from outside the fold of the so-called ''village community''. Dr. Ambedkar was right. Panchayati raj may well become a means of perpetuating social stasis. It is only under certain conditions that it can aid social transformation. Unless, therefore, panchayati raj is conceptualized, organized and structured in a manner that explicitly locates it within a context of social transformation, as accelerating that transformation, it will have little to commend it.

Several conclusions follow from this second approach. First, as already mentioned, the devolution of funds and powers from the state government to panchayats, must be ''optimal'' rather than ''maximal''. Secondly, panchayati raj is not an instrument for weakening the State structure for the pursuit of some ''communitarian'' objective (I use the word State here in the larger political sense, not in the sense of state governments), but a means of strengthening the democratic State as a whole, of which the panchayats are also a part, through whose intervention alone can the task of social transformation be carried out in a country like ours. Thirdly, this strengthened State structure must have the dual task of both overcoming millennia-old oppression and exploitation within the country, and resisting the hegemony of imperialism in order to preserve our freedom. The ''governance arrangement'' view of panchayati raj for instance often slips into arguing that panchayats should be allowed to have direct relationships with multilateral agencies dominated by the powerful nations, since they would then be able to raise more resources and promote more ''development''. Quite apart from the question of whether access to such resources causes genuine ''development'', this move has the potential of providing entry for such agencies to the Indian countryside and thereby facilitating imperialist hegemony.

Since each of these approaches has far-reaching implications, students of panchayati raj, especially in a state like Kerala, where decentralization has proceeded further than elsewhere in the country and where there is a strong and enlightened radical tradition, must distinguish between them and debate them thoroughly.
 

Print this Page

 

Site optimised for 800 x 600 and above for Internet Explorer 5 and above
© MACROSCAN 2009