Print this page
Themes > Features
21.03.2000

Urban Employments in the 1990s

Suddenly, employment concerns are back on the political and policy agenda. For more than a decade now, economic policy discussion in India had relegated employment generation to a subsidiary position, instead emphasising "efficiency" and "productivity growth" as the primary aims of government economic policy. In the process, neglect by official policy combined with the other side-effects of the economic strategy to create a situation of relative stagnation of employment, which has now once again become a matter of public concern.
 
Thus, recently Prime Minister Vajpayee has expressed concern at the inadequate generation of productive employment in the country. Of course, he then ascribed the high levels of underemployment as reflective of the combination of technological change and population explosion, an explanation which is weak at best in terms of explaining recent trends in employment and unemployment. But in general this is reflective of a new attention in policy-making circles being granted to the issue of employment. At one level this is no more than a belated recognition that this area is not simply one which can be left to "just grow" on its own, which was the official attitude of the past decade.
 
The 1990s - the decade of "economic reforms" - was heralded by neo-liberal economists as a period which not just produce higher growth rates, but also involve a more general unleashing of productive forces leading to faster employment generation. Since there is no question that inadequate employment growth has been one of the major lacunae in the entire post-Independence development experience, this was obviously seen as a very desirable outcome, although the links were never really very carefully developed in the argument.
 
Thus, the basic assumptions were as follows : in the rural areas, higher prices for agricultural goods through the provision of export markets would act as incentives to more private investment and production, generating more employment in agriculture. Such agricultural expansion in turn would act as a stimulant for rural non-agricultural activities in a virtuous circle. In the urban areas, industrial deregulation along with export orientation would encourage more investment and new activity in labour-intensive manufacturing in keeping with perceived static comparative advantage, and therefore increase employment here as well.
 
These assumptions were not validated in the rural context, where (as discussed in Macroscan, Businessline, January 2000) employment growth in agriculture appears to have become more of a residual as non-agricultural job opportunities have slumped. In this article we consider the evidence on urban employment, and assess the validity of these neo-liberal assumptions which have become almost axiomatic in Indian policy debate.
 
Chart 1 and Chart 2 plot the pattern of work participation of urban men and women respectively over the 1990s. Male work participation rates show a fair amount of fluctuation around a fairly narrow band of between 50 and 53 per cent, and no clear trend is discernible, which in itself suggests that not much has changed in terms of dramatic increases in perceived employment opportunities.



For women, the picture is rather different. Here too there is fluctuation, but the overall trend appears to be one of decline. Indeed, the decline, on a point-to-point basis, is a very significant one for just a decade, by more than 4 percentage points from 15.6 per cent to 11.4 per cent. This is extremely interesting, for it suggests that the picture that was being painted in the early 1990s, of a process of "feminisation" of employment, especially export-oriented manufacturing at the margin, has not been substantial enough to counteract other forces which have made for downward pressure on work participation rates.
 
This point, and the related implications for the nature of economic participation by women in urban India over the 1990s, deserve some greater elaboration. Feminisation of employment had become one of the economic buzzwords of the 1990s, as the role played by female labour in the east Asian export boom became more widely recognised, and as many export-oriented producers even in India chose to employ more women. This preference for women was typically a reflection of their inferior status, because of lower reservation wages, acceptance of worse working conditions and willingness to work under much more fragile casual contracts whereby they could be hired and fired at will. But in turn the very process of such employment generation often played a role in changing gender equations and relative power in society, so that market-based economic participation by women began to be seen as an important means to their economic empowerment.
 
This was very much the received wisdom not only in India, but through Southeast Asia where the process was far more advanced, until the mid-to late 1990s. However, data relating to the latter part of the 1990s that have recently become available, suggest that the process of feminisation of work may have decelerated or even begun to reverse, even before the crisis of 1997. Thus, female shares of manufacturing employment began to decline in most of these countries by 1994 or even earlier, as the increased employment of women led to upward pressure on their wages, reducing the gender gap in wages, and also involved louder social demands for better working conditions for women workers. These pressures actually made them less attractive for employers, and the impetus to feminisation became less marked.
 
Such a reverse process naturally raises the uncomfortable question of how the market participation of women workers can be encouraged without inevitably relying on worse conditions of work and greater fragility of such employment. In India, the question is even more pressing, because formal feminisation of work is still relatively less developed, although there is evidence that it is on the increase.
 
Thus, one of the more important forms of women's work has become in home-based work as part of subcontracting networks that can extend all the way from large (often multinational) companies down through various subcontracted units to women working on a piece-rate basis at wages that are often below the breadline. This is possible because women are still seen as subsidiary earners in households and the widespread extent of underemployment makes any remuneration, however little and unfair, seem attractive as part of the material survival strategy of poor urban households.
 
Open unemployment rates are shown in Chart 3 and Chart 4. In countries like India, as is well known, open unemployment rates are very poor indicators of the actual levels of job availability, because the material circumstances and absence of public social security systems mean that most workers have little choice but to find some employment, however unremunerative. Underemployment or disguised unemployment, which is far more difficult to estimate and measure, is therefore the most common tendency.



It is true that there is more likely to be recognition of open unemployment in urban areas where surplus labour is less easily disguised as work in the fields. However, even here, the proliferation of informal activities, mostly in the service sector, can serve as a way of camouflaging the actual extent of underemployment. This is of course another reason why data on service sector employment in countries like India need to be viewed with some degree of caution.
 
Even given these caveats, the evidence from the NSS thin samples shows that rates of unemployment for both men and women have been rather high over the 1990s. Already at the start of the decade, the rates were relatively high, indeed 50 per cent more than the average rates of the previous decade. After dipping a little in the mid-90, by 1998 the male rates were even higher (at 5.3 per cent) than in 1990-91, while the female rates were as high (at 8.1 per cent).
 
It should be noted that these higher unemployment rates in the latter part of the period are still not enough to explain the overall decline in work force participation of women, because the period when unemployment rates were lowest (1995-96) was also one when work force participation was low.
 
In terms of employment by sector, there is no clear evidence of any systematic pattern for urban males over the while period from the mid-1970s to the late 1990s (Chart 5 and 6). Indeed, what is surprising is that despite a brief period of falling share between 1995 and 1997, by the end of the period the impression is that of the stubborn persistence of the primary sector (at between 9 and 10 per cent of employment).



Nor is there much evidence of any increase or major trend in the share of the secondary sector in male employment - over the entire period it has remained broadly between 32 and 34 per cent of total male employment. The only evident shift is that of an increase in the share of the tertiary sector, from around 55 per cent to more than 58 per cent, but this is a shift that is essentially established by the beginning of the 1990s, and the last decade does not show any further tendency in this direction.
 
For women workers, there are more evident changes in terms of sectoral shifts. At the start of the period, in the late 1970s, all three sectors commanded roughly equal shares of female employment at around one-third each. Over the entire period there is a continuous pattern of decline in the proportion of primary sector employment, although this tendency itself decelerates over the 1990s. Secondary sector employment shares remain approximately stable, with if anything a slight decrease over the 1990s, belying the expectation of feminisation of manufacturing employment. The significant shift is in terms of increased employment in the tertiary sector, whose share goes up by more than 14 percentage points over the entire period. This trend is one that carries into the 1990s.
 
For male workers, while the sectoral shifts in employment may not be very marked, there is a much sharper tendency that emerges with respect to type of employment. In context like that of urban India, there is a general perception that regular employment is the most desirable, not only because of the security of contract that it offers, but also because it is typically associated with better wages and working conditions.
 
While it is true that some kinds of self-employment at the upper ends of the value added spectrum and in certain of the newer "sunrise" service sector areas do offer attractive work opportunities for skilled professionals, in general most self-employed workers in the service sector are those in low-remuneration informal sector activities with very insecure work conditions. This being the case, the decline in regular employment, and the relative increase in both self-employment and casual work, that are shown in Chart 7, are generally indicative of greater insecurity of working conditions.

While self-employment does show a fluctuating trend, the increase in the share of male casual employment is much more marked. This is not a new tendency - it has been noted in India, in both rural and urban areas, for several decades now, but the 1990s average is especially high in this regard. Such a tendency would probably be welcomed by those who see in this an indication of greater "flexibility" in the labour market, but in the context of the other trends already identified, what it tells us is that male workers are increasingly working in more fragile and vulnerable conditions, and despite this urban employment generation remains inadequate at best and even less dynamic than in earlier periods.
 
For women workers, however, the picture is more mixed and there are some positive signs as well. The tendencies are shown in Chart 8. Thus, while self-employment has been coming down fairly systematically over the entire period, there are increases in the share of both casual employment and regular employment. While the increased significance of casual employment has all the problematic implications that it has for male workers, the increase in the importance of regular employment should be welcomed. The inference could be made that most of this has occurred in service sectors, in both public and private sector employment, since as we have seen above, this is the sector whose share has been growing fastest for women workers as well.

To some extent, this pattern is mirrored in what is happening to organised sector employment. The deceleration and even decline in organised sector employment is one of the more disconcerting features of the 1990s, especially given that industrial output has increased manifold and the service sector in which much of the organised employment is based has been the most dynamic element in national income growth.
 
Despite this, not only has organised sector employment expansion slowed down considerably compared to the earlier decade, it has actually fallen in absolute terms for male workers. Chart 9 describes the pattern of male organised employment across public and private sectors. It is evident that the fall is due to the collapse in public sector employment, a denouement which has been greatly welcomed by economic liberalisers who see in this tendency a reduction of the large-scale overmanning still present in government and the public sector generally.

While public sector employment has fallen especially in the latter part of the period under consideration, private organised sector employment has continued to increase, albeit slowly. But this increase has simply not been enough to compensate for the decline in public employment, so that total male organised sectors employment has fallen slightly over the decade, as shown in Chart 11. Since organised sector work is still the most desired form of employment for male workers, this is an unfortunate tendency which adds to the other variables suggesting that overall employment conditions facing Indian men have worsened over the decade.



For women workers, by contrast, there has been a slight increase in aggregate organised sector employment evident in Chart 11. Chart 10 indicates that this has been due to increases in both public and private employment, although the increase is slightly sharper for private organised employment. Nevertheless, while such employment has increased, the numbers are nowhere near large enough in relation to the sizeable increase in terms of absolute numbers of female labour force over the same period. Also, this increase is still not enough to prevent a substantial deceleration in aggregate organised sector employment over the 1990s.
 
What all this suggests is that the pattern of growth over the 1990s has not been one which has generated sufficient employment even in the urban areas. This belies the expectations of those who had pushed for the economic strategy of the 1990s, that deregulation and trade liberalisation would be adequate incentives to more employment-intensive economic activity.
 
There are several reasons for this outcome, which is in because of rather than in spite of, the types of economic policies that have been pursued. Thus, these policies have systematically worked against the interests of most small producers, who account for not only e most labour-intensive forms of urban production but also the dominant part of urban manufacturing employment. Thus, the reduction of priority sector credit allocation, the shift in emphasis in terms of financing investment from banks to the stock market (where most small players simply cannot enter) the removal of various export subsidies from which small-scale exporters benefited, have all militated against the interests and viability of such enterprises.
 
Meanwhile, public investment in vital urban infrastructure has declined considerably, and public "cost-cutting" and other practices have also reduced the efficiency and accessibility of the infrastructure that currently exists because of inadequate maintenance. These not only create important bottlenecks for all producers, they also add to costs in general.
 
On top of all this, there is the pressure coming from newly freed imports becoming available at ever lower average rates of tariff. Such import competition is particularly difficult for small scale producers to meet, not only because of the greater control of many large companies over distributive networks, but also because they are unable to match the huge advertising budgets of larger companies and multinationals in particular. The role played by such import competition in reducing the viability of small enterprises and therefore in exerting downward pressure on urban employment in particular, should not be underestimated.
 
Meanwhile, as exporters strive to become or remain competitive in an increasingly difficult international environment, they are forced not only to find various ways of making labour more "flexible" than ever (through lower wages and more insecure working conditions), but also to adopt relatively capital-intensive new technologies that can ensure the quality and consistency that are required in world markets. This means that employment elasticities of production in such sectors tend to decline consistently, and so they also cannot be looked upon as large sources of potential employment generation.
 
If these patterns are to be halted or reversed, then the entire economic strategy obviously needs to be reworked. This is likely to become a more pressing concern as the social and political tensions that are released by such open or disguised unemployment become more obvious. As these exacerbate, it will no longer be enough for the rulers of the day to blame it all on technology and population, and they may be forced to consider alternative paths of industrialisation and development that actually put productive employment generation and poverty reduction at the forefront of the aims of public policy.

 

© MACROSCAN 2000