The Crop Insurance Scandal
Oct 15th 2004, Jayati Ghosh
Ramaswami, a farmer of Burugupally village in Mahbubnagar district of Andhra Pradesh, has been paying the premium for crop insurance every year for ten years now. His crop has failed completely twice in this period, and failed substantially more than three times. This year as well, he can point to the acres of dry and useless maize plants on his fields, destroyed by the late rains and prolonged dry spells of this monsoon. He estimates that he is unlikely to receive even ten per cent of the output he had anticipated.

Yet he has never received any insurance compensation at all for the repeated crop failures, and even this year he is unlikely to receive any benefit in return for the hefty insurance premium that he has paid so regularly. And what is the reason? The average crop output is his mandal has not fallen below 60 per cent of the average of the past four years, and so he is not deemed to be eligible for compensation. This is so even though the mandal and the district as a whole have been declared as drought-affected areas.

Ramaswami is frustrated and cynical about crop insurance, and given a choice he would certainly avoid paying the premium again. But he has no choice. In order to get a crop loan from a commercial bank, he must necessarily take on the insurance as well. The premium can be high - it ranges from 2 per cent to 7 per cent depending upon the crop. The premium is typically taken by the bank as an additional loan, on which interest is charged; or in some cases the amount is even compulsorily ''pre-paid'', that is deducted from the amount transferred as loan to the farmer.

The entire system of crop insurance in rural India is bizarre in the extreme. The farmer is not compensated for individual crop loss, but has to be treated as one of the entire group in the area, and the unit for calculation is taken to be the mandal (or block in other states). There is wide variation in soil types, cultivation conditions and even rainfall within mandals, and so the average disguises a large range of crop output. Some farmers may lose their entire crop even when the average for the mandal is normal.

In these circumstances, linking compensation payments to the average crop performance of the mandal is extremely unfair. It is akin to linking payments of life insurance claims to the average death rate in a particular area, rather than the death of the individual who has taken out the policy.

What explains this extraordinary system, which adds to the burden on farmers without providing any compensation to so many genuine cases? The answer lies in the way in which the system of crop insurance was introduced, and the inflexible manner in which it is currently being pursued.

Some well-meaning policy-makers at the Centre decided some years ago that anyone taking a crop loan from an institutional source should also take on crop insurance. And so the public insurance companies were instructed to provide crop insurance - which could be linked to the loans - to farmers. This was an excellent idea, except that the insurance companies were not provided with the additional staff that is necessary to supervise and implement the provision of crop loans. In fact, they were encouraged instead to ''downsize'' and reduce staff in order to cut costs, even when serving rural areas.

As a consequence, because of shortage of staff, the public insurance companies are simply not in a position to undertake the examination of fields which would be required to provide an individual insurance policy and deal with individual claims along the lines of other insurance products. So they have fallen back on a system of averages, and that too, of a relatively large area, and linked individual payments to the average performance of the area.

Because of the requirements of assessing the potential and the crop-cutting experiments required to assess the actual yield in any given year, the insurance companies are even reluctant to bring the assessment unit down to the individual village, since that would increase costs.

What makes matters worse in some areas is that in many parts of rural India, rainfall conditions over the past few years have been well below historical norms. In western Rayalaseema region of Andhra Pradesh, for example, as in northern Telengana, the past five years have received rainfall which is around 15-20 per cent below the historical (for the past fifty years) average. These regions are already low rainfall areas, with only between 500-600 mm per year, and so even small reductions in the average can have very damaging effects.

The past few years have been exceptionally poor in rain in these areas, and therefore also have been associated with much worse output. To take this low performance as the reference period is to make the conditions for compensation for farmers even more onerous.

The crop insurance has therefore become no more than a loan insurance, which insures the lenders at the cost of the farmers who have to pay the premium. The unfair system, which is in sharp contrast to the other schemes of insurance available in other sectors and for individuals, provides yet another example of how so many systems in our economy are weighted against cultivators.
 

Site optimised for 800 x 600 and above for Internet Explorer 5 and above
© MACROSCAN 2004