The Alibi of the Need for FDI
The case for financial liberalization as a total package is ultimately argued on the grounds of the presumed need for FDI. Prime Minister Manmohan Singh pleaded before a bunch of financiers in New York that unless India got $150 billion FDI over a 15 year period to improve her infrastructure, her economic prospects were bleak. This cringing before metropolitan finance, though it started with the NDA and hence predates the UPA, certainly marks a enormous departure from the earlier days, when Prashanta Chandra Mahalanobis had gone lecturing all over America about how India was embarking on a massive industrialization effort on her own and with her own resources. The favourite ploy of our current leaders of course is to cite the example of China which these days gets around $50 billion FDI each year compared to $3-4 billion of India: the suggestion is made that without such heavy investment China could not achieve her extraordinary growth rates, and that if India wanted such high growth rates then she too would have to woo FDI assiduously.

This argument is wrong on several counts. First, the large influx of FDI is hardly necessary at present for China"s remarkable growth performance. China, as is well-known, has massive and growing foreign exchange reserves which are built up out of her own earnings in the form of current account surpluses, and not through speculative financial inflows as in the case of India. She is in other words maintaining an excess of savings over non-FDI-financed investment. Her need for investible resources from outside therefore is correspondingly less. FDI in her case could be a useful means of bringing in technology or of marketing her products, but for these purposes technical collaboration or marketing agreements could do as well. Her reasons for large FDI inflows at present therefore remain obscure. At any rate, inflows on this scale are certainly unnecessary for the maintenance of her growth rate. Secondly, FDI typically flows into those economies which already have high domestic savings rates anyway. It does not constitute a means of compensating for low domestic savings. Since India has a savings rate much lower than in the East and South East Asian countries, and since this rate has not gone up at all during the period of "liberalization", to pin hopes on FDI to provide a way out of this situation is a chimera. Thirdly, in the case of India, as suggested earlier, there is plenty of unutilized capacity, within the public sector itself, which can be used with impunity for boosting public investment through an enlarged fiscal deficit, without even having to raise tax revenue.

In short, FDI is both unnecessary for boosting India"s growth rate and unlikely to come in any significant quantities, despite all the blandishments being offered. But since these blandishments include financial liberalization, which necessarily engenders deflation and cut backs in public investment, that in turn have a discouraging effect on private investment, all this wooing of FDI in the name of stepping up the investment ratio is paradoxically having the opposite effect of dampening the investment ratio.
The blandishments include an increase in the foreign equity cap in critical sectors. The first UPA budget, for 2004-05, had identified telecom, civil aviation and insurance sectors as the ones in which the level of permissible foreign equity holdings would increase. The FDI cap has already been lifted in the civil aviation sector (from 40 to 49 percent), and on February 2 the government cleared a proposal to raise the FDI limit in telecom from 49 to 74 percent. But these precisely are sectors where foreign investment is not only unnecessary but positively harmful. In the case of telecom moreover there are serious security considerations involved in having majority foreign-owned companies. The idea seems more to give foreign capital a finger in the profitable pie that is the Indian market, at a time when metropolitan capital in these sectors is desperately looking for outlets elsewhere, than to bring any benefits to the Indian economy. The Left has been fiercely resisting these measures, but these unfortunately do not need parliamentary approval.

Pension Funds
The latest move of the UPA government to let pension funds be used in the stock-market and pensioners take the risk of loss, is yet another "liberalization" measure with serious consequences for an extremely vulnerable section of the population. But it is not just a matter of how these funds are used. The 2005-06 budget permits the entry of FDI into the pension sector. In effect therefore the government is planning to hand over pension funds to MNCs for the purpose of speculating on the stock-market.

The argument often advanced that the burden on the exchequer on account of pension payment obligations is becoming too heavy is unacceptable. It is the solemn duty of the government to meet whatever burden pension payment obligations impose upon it, and it has to find the resources to fulfill it. Considering the fact that 50 percent of the pension payment obligations are on account of the armed forces, demurring at discharging this duty is in particularly bad taste.

But then, even some well-meaning observers point out, since the pensioners would be exposed to the possibility not just of losses but of gains as well, they may even end up being much better off from the proposed measure. Why should they object to it? The reasons are simple: first, any person would be the most risk-averse when it is his or her pension funds which are at stake; and secondly, the risks are far greater than usually supposed. They arise not only from the fact that the stock market fluctuates wildly, but also from the fact that the pensioners could well become victims of unscrupulous speculators using their funds.

This last point is often missed: in a country like ours the political empowerment of the people is far greater than their legal empowerment. They have a much better chance of getting redress through political pressure than they have of getting redress through legal action. They are safer when their claims are with the State than they are when these claims are on some private speculators. To leave pensioners to the mercy of a bunch of speculators by allowing the latter to play the market with their funds would be an almost criminal dereliction of duty on the part of the State which the Left has rightly vowed to resist to the bitter end.

The Patent Amendment Act
There are two areas where the government has yielded some ground under pressure from the Left. One is in the area of patents; and the other is the current year"s budget. Let us examine these.

India had a Patent system introduced through an Act in 1970 which was highly appreciated by progressive opinion all over the world. Among other things it kept the prices of drugs low, and did so by not recognizing product patents. No patentee in other words could prevent someone else producing the same good using some process other than the one which had been patented. This enabled the domestic production of drugs, which had been developed abroad, by using a different process. Domestic substitutes of drugs developed abroad could therefore be locally produced and sold cheap. The TRIPS agreement under the WTO permitted product patents, and allowed a 20 year life-span for patents compared to the 7 years under the Indian Patents Act 1970. The WTO agreement which was signed without taking the parliament"s prior permission, enjoined on India the obligation to amend her Patents Act to make it TRIPS-compatible.

The WTO agreement however, like all international agreements, has provisions and loopholes which could still be exploited to the benefit of the Indian people while amending the 1970 Act for TRIPS-compatibility. In other words, the term "TRIPS-compatibility" is itself a matter of interpretation, and any government that is concerned with the welfare of the common people, should naturally use an interpretation that safeguards their interests to the maximum extent, even assuming the we have to fall in line over "TRIPS-compatibility". But the NDA government brought in amendments that showed scant respect for the people"s welfare and passed an ordinance incorporating them. The UPA not only re-issued the ordinance, but proposed an amended Act that was an exact carbon copy of the NDA"s proposed legislation. This has been changed under pressure from the Left and the amended Act, though TRIPS-compatible, protects the people much better. To be sure the very introduction of product patents has deleterious consequences, and in that sense any amendment of the 1970 Act is retrograde. But within the framework of the WTO, the amended Act is much better than the NDA/UPA Draft.

This becomes clear if we take a look at the demands made by a Peoples" Commission which operated with the aim of getting the most out of the existing TRIPS agreement. Its main demands were as follows:
"(i).. The term "invention" should be reserved for a "basic novel product or process involving an inventive step and capable of industrial application". All three criteria, "novelty", "inventive step" and the quality of being "capable of industrial application", must be insisted upon. (ii)…The proposed amendments allow patenting of micro-organisms. This must not happen. Micro-organisms, including viruses, should not be patented, and hence should also figure alongside plants and animals, including seeds, varieties and species, in the list of non-patentable items… (iii)… The proposed amendment provides no scope for compulsory licensing in cases where, notwithstanding the offer of reasonable commercial terms and conditions to the patent holder by an enterprise, the patentee does not respond within a stipulated period of time. In all such cases compulsory licensing is permitted even within the framework of TRIPS Article 31 (a) and (b), and countries like Brazil and China have passed legislation allowing compulsory licensing. This omission from the proposed amendment must be remedied forthwith. (iv) …In all cases where compulsory licenses are granted, even though the production is supposed to be "predominantly" for supply in the domestic market of the country in question, exporting should also be explicitly allowed… (v) …Where applications have been received during the transitional period 1.1.1995 to 31.12.2004, … patents, if granted, would be effective from the latter date for a period of twenty years from the date of application. In all such cases if any production activity has been started by any enterprise during the transition period, then that enterprise should be allowed to continue production on payment of a nominal royalty to the patent-holder, after the patent has been granted, instead being accused of violating the patent. (vi) …The magnitude of royalty payment should be explicitly stipulated within a range, say 4-5 percent, of the sales turnover at ex-factory price. (vii) … Since the TRIPS Agreement itself provides no explicit system of examination of any pre-grant opposition to the grant of a patent, the existing provision in the Indian Patents Act 1970, which is being sought to be amended, should be retained."

It is noteworthy that all these suggestions, barring (ii) and (vi) were incorporated in the amended draft of the Act owing to the Left"s insistence, and that (ii) has been referred to an experts" committee. At the same time however the necessity for mobilizing public opinion in favour of a re-negotiation of the WTO, including in particular the TRIPS agreement, remains. Unless a strong public opinion is built up the correlation of political forces cannot be changed to a point where we can either reject or go beyond the existing framework of the TRIPS agreement.

The 2005-06 Budget
The 2005-06 budget differed from other recent budgets both in its rhetoric and in the somewhat larger allocations it made for social sectors and rural development, including employment generation. The absolute amounts involved of course were still very small, and even these small provisions may not materialize if on account of tax shortfalls, which are bound to arise this year, as they did last year, owing to the significant overestimation of tax receipts in the budget, the Fiscal responsibility and Budgetary Management Act comes into play and expenditures have to be scaled down. Even so, the change is noteworthy.

This change however does not signify any shift away from the neo-liberal package of policies. On the contrary many of its suggestions like opening up the mining and pension sectors to foreign direct investment, encouraging crop diversification at the expense of foodgrain self-sufficiency, the reductions in customs duties on a range of capital goods, and the cut in corporate income tax rate from 35 to 30 percent on domestic capitalists, are all measures emanating from the neo-liberal perspective. And when one adds to this the pronouncements of the Economic Survey on capital account convertibility and on "labour market reform" (which means in effect the institutionalization of the right to retrench), it is clear that no change of direction away from neo-liberalism is being contemplated.

Two questions immediately arise. First, how is it that within a regime committed to neo-liberalism, additional financial resources have been found for rural development and social sectors? The Finance Minister appears to have given out substantial tax concessions all around and yet managed to increase the Gross Budget Support for the Plan by 16.9 percent over the previous year (BE to BE) and the Budget Support for the Central Plan by 25.6 percent, even while ensuring a marginal reduction in the fiscal deficit to 4.3 percent of the GDP. For a government that till the other day kept asking "Where is the money?" when any worthwhile proposal was mooted, including a universal EGA, this is a remarkable turnaround. How has this become possible? Secondly, does the fact that the government has made larger provision for rural development and social sectors while remaining committed to a neo-liberal course suggest that we have finally arrived at "liberalization with a human face", contradicting the claim made above that the two cannot go together? Let us discuss these seriatim.

The answer to the first question, about the source of financial resources, is simple: the budget manages to balance its figures through substantial "window dressing", both in the matter of the expected tax revenue and in the matter of the expected fiscal deficit.

With the reduction in corporate tax rate, with the removal of a large number of service providers from the purview of the service tax, with the lightening of the income tax burden, with the reduction in customs duties on a large number of items, especially capital goods, and with significant concessions in the excise duties on several items, the Finance minister's claim that his indirect tax proposals would be broadly revenue neutral and that his direct tax proposals would garner Rs.6000 cr. extra, appears untenable, notwithstanding the 50 paise cess on petrol and diesel, and the slightly heavier taxation on "health hazard" goods. But even if his claim is accepted, the tax revenue calculations still appear grossly unrealistic. If we assume a generous 9 percent growth in real terms of the non-agricultural sector during 2005-06, and a 6 percent rate of inflation, the nominal growth rate of this sector comes to 15 percent. At existing tax rates the tax revenue cannot be expected to increase at a rate much higher than this. And if additional tax revenue mobilization is a small Rs.6000 cr., it follows that total tax revenue should also increase at around 15 percent. Instead we find an expected tax revenue increase, compared to 2004-05 (RE), of 21 percent, clearly an overestimate. This would not matter if the Finance Minister chooses not to be tied down by the FRBM, a silly piece of legislation as we have seen; but if he does, then the positive features of the budget would be undermined.

The second area of "window-dressing" is with reference to the fiscal deficit. There is a substantial "off-loading" of borrowing from the budget to off-budget entities. At least three deserve mention. The first is State governments. The Budget documents show what at first glance appears a rather surprising reduction in total capital expenditure, and correspondingly in the Gross Budgetary Support for the Plan. Plan Expenditure for instance falls from Rs.145590 cr. last year to Rs.143497 cr. this year (BE to BE). The Finance Minister however claimed that the Gross Budgetary Support (on a comparable definition to what was used earlier) would be Rs.172500 cr. for 2005-06. The reason for this discrepancy lies in the fact that following the Twelfth Finance Commission's report, State governments would be borrowing around Rs.29000 cr. for their Plans from the market. Earlier the Centre would have borrowed this amount and handed it to the States, but now the States themselves would have to go the market.

This represents an offloading of the fiscal deficit from the Centre to the States. In addition it is fraught with potentially serious consequences. States may not be able to get the loans on reasonable terms, especially in these financially "liberal" times (when even the captive market for government and government-approved securities provided by the Statutory Liquidity Ratio is being abandoned according to this year's budget); some States may not be able to raise their loan requirements from the market at all. True, the Centre which earlier had the sole prerogative of market borrowing charged the States exorbitant rates on the loans it provided to them; but the solution to that lies in regulating the rate at which the Centre can lend to the States (pegging it for instance at certain fixed percentage points below the average nominal growth rate of the GDP) rather than having the States borrow directly from the market which could even be a prelude to the fracturing of the nation's unity (if States started borrowing freely from international agencies).

The second instance of implicit off-loading of the fiscal deficit is with regard to the Infrastructure Development Fund, whose capital of Rs.10000 cr., which is supposed to provide "bridge finance" for infrastructure projects that are remunerative economically but not financially, is not provided for in the budget. Instead of borrowing directly, the government, in other words, is making an agency set up by itself do the borrowing. This borrowing, being off-budget, is not shown as part of the fiscal deficit.

The third instance is the absence of any reference to the food component of the Employment Programmes in the budget documents. The 5 million tonnes which the Finance Minister has promised as the food component of the Food For Work programme and which does not figure in the budget will obviously be loaned by the FCI to the FFW programme. A part of the fiscal deficit is thus shifted out of the budget by making the FFW borrow from the FCI instead of getting funds from the government which would have had to borrow for the purpose.

For these reasons the actual fiscal deficit generated by the budgetary provisions is much larger than what appears in the documents. One cannot fault this in principle. On the contrary it only confirms the point that the FRBM Act which forces the government to do such "off-loading" of the fiscal deficit away from the budget to other government organizations is a nuisance which even people like Mr.Chidambaram have come to realize.

But it is more than a nuisance. The practice of "off-loading" which it implicitly encourages can have positively harmful implications. For instance, such "off-loading" may, given the general neo-liberal ethos, jeopardize the future of the agencies on to whose shoulders the deficit is being off-loaded: State governments, as already mentioned, might turn into proteges of agencies like the ADB and the World Bank (which some of them are already in the process of becoming) under these circumstances. This could damage the integrity of the nation. Likewise if the FCI's giving loans to the FFW programme increases its own deficit (which is covered through the food subsidy), then in the name of cutting the food subsidy the same government might decide to wind up the FCI. In other words, enlarging the fiscal deficit whether directly through the budget or through other government agencies is fine provided a consistent approach of defending the government agencies is simultaneously adopted.. But, one cannot be sure of this.

Besides, while enlarging the fiscal deficit for incurring larger expenditure is perfectly legitimate in a demand-constrained system, there is little justification for doing so together with a reduction in corporate income taxation. The argument that some parity has to be established between personal income taxation and corporate income taxation has no basis whatsoever. Hence the argument that since the highest rate of personal income tax is 30 percent, the rate of corporate income tax must also be reduced to 30 percent from the current 35 percent lacks substance.

Indeed most of the tax concessions given in the budget lack any justification. There is no reason why the scope of the service tax should be cut down from its existing level. There is no reason why import duties should be reduced on a variety of capital goods: while it would have a scarcely noticeable effect on the overall investment, it would act to the detriment of the domestic capital goods producers, causing a degree of de-industrialization in this sector, which would also follow from the de-reservation of a number of items hitherto reserved for the small-scale sector. Likewise, there is also no reason for reducing the excise duties on a variety of luxury goods like air-conditioners. And the reduction in import tariffs on a range of agricultural goods is precisely the opposite of what the government should be doing if it wished to undo the damage done to this sector by neo-liberalism. Even experts like M.S.Swaminathan have been arguing that agriculture cannot be treated like any other sector in the matter of protection, since the livelihood of millions of peasants and labourers who have nowhere else to go depends upon it. The budget alas pays scant heed to such sage advice.

While these tax concessions are being given, the imposition of a cess of 50 paise per litre on petrol and diesel appears uncalled for, especially as it comes on top of price-hikes decreed very recently on these commodities. The relief which the budget provides by way of reductions in import and excise duties on kerosene and LPG would be offset to an extent by this cess. In the case of petrol the net revenue raising effect is much less than what appears at first sight since the government is a major consumer of the commodity. In the case of diesel, any price hike jacks up transport costs and has an across-the-board inflationary impact which should have been avoided.

Two suggestions thrown out in the budget are a source of disquiet. The first relates to the banking sector where the bounds on the Statutory Liquidity Ratio and the Cash Reserve Ratio are sought to be removed and the Reserve Bank made free to prescribe such prudential norms as it deems fit. This entails giving greater autonomy to the RBI and making banks free in their portfolio choice which would enable them to speculate more freely. Both these, like the earlier pronouncement regarding making the management of public sector banks more autonomous, are measures of financial liberalization which would have adverse consequences for the economy. The Finance Minister who talks of giving more credit to agriculture in one breath, cannot advocate financial liberalization in the next without inviting the charge of not being serious about the former objective.

The second disquieting suggestion relates to the entry of foreign direct investment into mining and pension funds. The case of pension funds we have already examined above. As regards mining, the argument against FDI is obvious. Indeed, as Joan Robinson, the well-known Cambridge economistmentioned earlier, had once remarked, of all the different areas of FDI involvement, the mining sector is the worst, since minerals are an exhaustible resource. The MNCs extract the mineral, ship the surplus back home, and leave when the mine gets exhausted. But when that happens, the country is left high and dry, with no more mineral resource left. The case of Myanmar illustrates the point. At one time its oil wealth attracted much foreign investment (Burma-Shell), and it experienced for a brief period an enormous boom, when oil extraction was going on. But today, with its oil wealth exhausted, it is one of the forty "least developed" countries in the world. There is absolutely no argument whatsoever for inducting MNCs into the mining sector.

This brings us to our second question: is the budget an embodiment of "liberalization with a human face"? The fact that patently neo-liberal measures are being contemplated by a Finance Minister who has ostensibly shown concern for the poor, only demonstrates that this budget is an attempt to please all, the MNcs, the corporate sector, the salariat and, to an extent the poor and those who speak for them. Such a "please-all" budget can only be based on a degree of arithmetical jugglery and hence can only be a transitory phenomenon. Or putting it differently, this budget does not mark the ushering in of a "growth-with-equity" trajectory, or of "liberalization with a human face". It rather represents a temporary tactical compromise, a tactical adjustment in the march along a neo-liberal path, which has been necessitated by the relentless pressure exerted on the "liberalizers" by the Left.

Concluding Observations
The last few months of the functioning of the UPA government reveal clearly the bind in which it is caught. It cannot openly discard the Common Minimum Programme to which it is ostensibly committed; it cannot push ahead with impunity with the neo-liberal programme which international finance capital enjoins upon it. Its attempts to browbeat the Left to allow it to discard the CMP for a neo-liberal programme have failed. Some bourgeois commentators, impatient with this situation, have even started flying kites about a "grand coalition" between the Congress and the BJP, which in effect means a "grand coalition" between sections drawn from both these Parties. What these commentators fail to understand is that even if such a grand coalition were to come about, which is a tall order anyway, it would not get the mandate of the people who have expressed their rejection of neo-liberal policies in the May elections. The bind of the government is really the outward manifestation of an interregnum, a stand-off between the forces aligned to international finance capital on the one hand and the popular forces on the other. As the latter become more organized, conscious and effective, the present situation would change in a more favourable direction for the progressive movement.

<< Previous Page | 1 | 2 |

 

Site optimised for 800 x 600 and above for Internet Explorer 5 and above
© MACROSCAN 2005