The third measure that is being experimented with is a sharp hike, pre-budget possibly, in excise duties. To this end the government has by ordinance armed itself with the right to impose excise duties in excess of 100 per cent. While justified on the basis of the likelihood of (or need for?) war, given the dispute with Pakistan over the terrorist issue, the real reason for this move appears to be the desperation to government’s own self-imposed but unsuccessful war on the fiscal deficit. Speculation has it (The Hindu, January 10, 2002) that the hike in excise duties would be focussed on petroleum products, with the implicit proviso that the burden of the enhanced duty would not be passed on to the consumers just now, so that the initiative does not meet with opposition. This would result in losses for the petroleum companies and an increase in the oil pool deficit currently placed at Rs. 8000 crore. But the oil companies too would not have to finally pay, since with the dismantling of the administered price mechanism in April, the government would have to issue bonds to the oil companies to finance their deficit.

The absurdity of any such move, if actually undertaken, should be obvious. To start with, since the bonds to be issued in April would have to be counted as part of the government’s borrowing requirement, the measure only amounts to transferring a part of this year’s deficit into next year’s budget. Further, since the higher excise duty would remain in place till reversed, it is likely that sometime later the companies would indeed make the consumers pay the duty and bear the burden of the cascading effects on prices that any increases in the prices of universal intermediates has. This meaningless move at the expense of consumers, if resorted to, would only be explained as an effort to garner immediately the Rs. 1500 to Rs. 2000 crore that the measure is expected to generate.

All this has become necessary because of the peculiar kind of fiscal crisis that neoliberal economic reforms in general and financial liberalisation in particular have generated. Trade liberalisation, which has included steep reductions in customs tariffs, has resulted in a fall in customs revenues accruing to the government. Further, the success of reform being predicated on a rise in private investment, the government has been offering a range of tax concessions as incentives to spur such investment. While these concessions have not been successful, they together with the loss in revenues from customs tariffs, have resulted in a decline in the ratio of central taxes to GDP to the tune of 1.5 to 2 percentage points. This implies that even when the fiscal deficit to GDP ratio is at levels close to where it was in the late 1980s, which has been true in at least a couple of years in the 1990s, the fiscal stimulus associated with that deficit has been far less. A lower tax-GDP ratio implies that the expenditure to GDP ratio associated with any given fiscal deficit would be lower.

If we combine this with the tendency for the fiscal deficit-to-GDP ratio to rule lower because of the kind of fiscal reform being adopted with the government, a basic tendency towards slower growth should be expected. For some time this tendency was being counteracted by special factors such as the post-reform boom in durable consumption attributable to the pent-up demand for such goods from the less liberal era. But once such counteracting factors lose their strength, as has happened in recent years, a recession is inevitable. The recession in turn reduces tax collections further, as has happened in the first nine months of fiscal 2001-02, aggravating the fiscal crisis.

But that is not all. Financial reform has forced the government to substitute less expensive borrowing with credit obtained at much higher interest rates. Not only do real interest rates tend to rule higher under reform to offer better returns to foreign financial investors but the government is forced to abjure borrowing from the central bank at much lower interest rates. Thus even the less efficacious fiscal deficit is partly accounted for by outlays on burgeoning interest payments and consists of a significant deficit on the revenue account of the government. This weakens the fiscal stimulus associated with a given deficit even further.

In the event, neither is the deficit low enough to satisfy the government, the international financial institutions and financial investors, nor does the stimulus provided by any deficit correspond to the apparent size of the deficit. The fiscal crisis in fact worsens, but the deficit it results in does not spur growth even when food stocks are aplenty, unutilised capacity abounds, inflation is low and foreign exchange reserves are comfortable. Pre-budget manoeuvres of the kind described would only contribute to the persistence of this paradoxical situation, while imposing heavier burdens on the poor and middle classes.

<< Previous Page | 1 | 2 |

 

Site optimised for 800 x 600 and above for Internet Explorer 5 and above
© MACROSCAN 2002