The
July 5 bandh against the recent hike in the administered prices
of petroleum products did shut much of the country down. This may or
may not shake UPA II out of its indifference to political and parliamentary
disagreement on the correctness of its manifestly elitist economic strategy
that favours industry, finance and the well-to-do over the common person.
But it does seem to mark a turning point in the six-year long innings
of the UPA in government. The claim that the UPA and its economist Prime
Minster had managed to build a consensus around the market-friendly,
pro-business, neoliberal strategy it pursues has been challenged not
just by the political opposition to it, but by the mass support that
opposition has received as reflected in the success of the bandh.
The fact that there is no such consensus, but only an artificial one
constructed by a governmental propaganda machinery and an elitist media,
is corroborated by many developments. For example, the myth that there
is no opposition to inflation partly because its effects are no more
so damaging (presumably because Indians on average are richer now and
can ''afford'' it) and partly because some inflation is recognized as
the unavoidable outcome of adjustments needed to promote growth, has
been exposed for what it is: a myth. Political circumstances may have
delayed strong public expression of anger, but such anger was clearly
there and is now visible on the streets. It has clearly not been diluted
by the periodic claims of apologists labelled as economists (non-resident,
imported or locally cloned) that if we wait a few months inflation would
just go away.
Second, the opposition is now strong enough to dismiss the malicious
propaganda used to delegitimize dissent against a callous set of policies
that penalise the poor for no reason other than the desire to reward
the insatiable appetites of India's rich. This propaganda of delegitimization
has many elements. That such dissent is merely the opportunistic coming
together of Left and Right for political gain and not because of conviction
about the correctness of their demands. That responding to such demands
would drive the exchequer bankrupt. That the opposition to such policies,
through a bandh for example, results in losses totalling thousands
of crores of rupees, as ''established'' by spurious estimates purveyed
by organisations such as the CII that represent the interests that benefit
from market-driven pricing.
Finally, the lack of consensus was reflected in the official advertising
campaign against the bandh launched by the Ministry of Petroleum
and Natural Gas. Recognising that opposition to the petroleum price
hike was receiving public support, the Ministry decided to drop any
pretence that there was a consensus and chose instead to manufacture
one. Poorly designed advertisements occupying substantial newspaper
space (at a cost of course), asserted that the price hike was a ''small
price'' to be paid today to ''reap big benefits tomorrow''. Besides
being opaque on what those benefits were and how they were to be derived
from a price hike, the ads gratuitously declared that the bandh
was ''not a solution''. It was another matter that none was arguing
that the bandh was a solution to anything other than governmental
intransigence. In any case, it was unclear which problem the Ministry
had in mind. In the event, the ads served no other purpose than that
of paying off some newspapers that were using their editorial columns
to justify the price hike and attack all opposition to it.
The opposition to the petrol price hike was as strong as it was because
the hike came in the midst of a prolonged inflationary crisis that the
government had failed to control. Coming when it did it also seemed
to signal that the government could not care less about the inflation
and its effects on the poor majority in this country that earns money
incomes that are not indexed to inflation, and are therefore experiencing
a decline in real (inflation-adjusted) incomes from their already abysmally
low levels.
Consider, for example, the aggregate rate of inflation as reflected
by the Wholesale Price Index (WPI). The WPI figures for May reflected
three worrying trends. First, for the fifth month in a row, the aggregate
annual rate of inflation as reflected in the month-on-month increase
in the WPI had been near or well above double-digit levels. The figures
for May put inflation at 10.2 per cent over the year. Second, this inflationary
surge was particularly sharp in the case of some essential commodities,
as a result of which the prices of food articles as a group had risen
by 16.5 per cent and of food grain by close to 10 per cent. Though food
inflation had declined to 12.9 per cent during the week ended June 19,
the figure was still high and reflected more a base effect rather than
a slowing of the extent of price increase. Finally, there were clear
signs that what was largely an inflation in food prices was being generalized
with fuel prices rising by 13 per cent and manufactured goods prices
by 6-7 per cent.
As has always been the case, the inflation in retail prices has been
much greater than at the wholesale level. The retail prices collated
by the Ministry of Consumer Affairs, Food and Public Distribution indicate
that the average of retail prices across centres all over the country
had as at the beginning of July increased over the previous two years
by 19 per cent in the case of rice and wheat, 58 per cent in the case
of tur dal, 71 per cent in the case of urad dal, 113.5 per cent in the
case of moong dal, 73 per cent in the case of sugar and 32 per cent
each in the case of potatoes and onion. By any count this is an astounding
rate of inflation, and a similar situation prevails in the case of vegetables
that are an important component in the food consumption basket of the
common person.
The government's periodic response has been that while inflation is
a matter for concern, the trend is likely to reverse itself. In his
inaugural address at a conference of Chief Ministers on prices of essential
commodities held in February this year, Prime Minister Manmohan Singh
said that the worst was over on the food inflation front and expressed
confidence that the Centre would soon be able to stabilise food prices.
It could not in practice because it did little and ignored important
structural influences on the pace of price increase in the current conjuncture.
One is the long-term neglect of agriculture which has affected the level
and pattern of agricultural production to an extent where supply-side
constraints are leading to inflation every time growth picks up. The
sudden and sharp hike in the support prices for pulses announced recently
is an acknowledgement of this problem by the government. However, given
the likely lag in output responses, the immediate fallout of that price
increase could be an aggravation of inflationary trends.
A second structural influence is the effect the government's policy
of reducing subsidies, raising administered prices and dismantling price
controls has on the costs of production. Finally, inflation is high
and persistent despite expectations of a normal or good monsoon because
the decision to give private trade a greater role in the markets for
essentials and permit futures trading in some essential commodities
has provided the basis for a new bout of speculation which the government
seems unable or unwilling to control.
While there is some consensus on the role of speculation in driving
inflation, official statements ignore the importance of liberalised
marketing arrangements and liberalised futures trading in ensuring that
speculative expectations of a rise in prices are realised. Moreover,
with its emphasis on subsidy reduction and targeting of food distributed
through the public distribution system, the Centre has paid little attention
to enhancing the spread and penetration of the PDS, making it a less
potent instrument to combat speculation. In fact, many states have complained
that they have not been allocated adequate supplies to cater to rising
demand, undermining the role of the PDS as a safeguard against inflation
in open market prices.
As opposed to focusing on these matters, the UPA government has sought
to divert attention and induce a sense of complacency about future price
trends. Besides periodically declaring that inflation would subside
in due course, the government has chosen to identify the inflation that
has been with us for the past few months as being the collateral fallout
of policies and developments elsewhere in the domestic and world economy.
For example, at the Chief Ministers' conference referred to above, among
the reasons reportedly cited for the price rise were increases in the
minimum support price for farm produce instituted to help the farming
community, increases in international prices, increases in demand ''due
to the increase in purchasing power'' resulting from higher growth,
excess liquidity in the system, ''inefficiencies'' in marketing of farm
produce and the high cost of intermediation. Many of the factors are
either out of the Centre's control or otherwise positive economic outcomes
that cannot be countered. This amounted to an implicit declaration that
food price inflation of some intensity is inevitable.
Moreover, in yet another indicator of it callousness, the Centre sought
to transfer the blame for inflation to the states. At the Chief Ministers'
conference the Prime Minister, who had earlier argued that the states
were not doing enough to deal with speculation, attributed the wide
gap between farm gate and retail prices partly to the proliferation
of State and local taxes, cesses and levies. Claiming that taxes on
food items added an additional cost burden of as much as 10-15 per cent
at the retail level, he implicitly suggested that the states should
forego revenues to neutralise some of the price increase. Besides this,
he made a case for enhancing competition at the retail level by opening
up the retail trade, though the evidence elsewhere is that this merely
increases concentration at the retail level and widens rather than reduces
trade margins. Not surprisingly, the Prime Minister's remarks, which
were hailed by senior executives of many domestic retail majors such
as the Future Group, were seen as a signal of the Government's intent
to allow a larger role for foreign companies in India's retail industry.
This was being done when, even in India, the evidence suggested that
allowing corporate (both domestic and foreign companies) to enter the
market for grains and other food items has led to some increase in concentration
of distribution. This has contributed to the widening of the gap between
farm gate and wholesale prices and the gap between wholesale and retail
prices. As a result farmers have benefited less from periods of high
prices even as consumers suffered, because the benefits are garnered
by middlemen. Whether it is agricultural, energy or industrial price
inflation, a few corporate and trading interests seem to be the principal
beneficiaries.
It is in this context that the recent decision to hike petroleum product
prices and the opposition it has generated need to be assessed. The
immediate and near-term impact of the oil price decisions would be an
aggravation of inflationary trends that currently burden the common
person. Petroleum products are consumed in some measure by all. Given
the fact that these products are universal intermediates, entering into
the costs of production of a number of goods and services, the cascading
effects of the price hike on the costs and prices of a range of commodities
is likely to be significant. With prices of essentials already on the
rise, the move threatens to make inflation the country's principal economic
problem. It follows, therefore, that this is the worst time for hikes
in and the decontrol of the prices of petroleum products.
The government claims that this was unavoidable because of the ''losses''
being suffered by the oil marketing companies (OMCs). When the domestic
prices of oil products are controlled but the price of imported oil
is rising, oil marketing companies receive from the consumer less than
what it costs them to acquire the products they distribute. This leads
to what are termed ''under-recoveries'', which would affect the accounts
of the oil marketing companies (Indian Oil Corporation, Bharat Petroleum
Corporation, Hindustan Petroleum Corporation and IBP) that obtain their
supplies of petrol and diesel from the refineries at prices that equal
their import price inclusive of customs duty. According to estimates,
if retail prices had not been raised under-recoveries by the oil marketing
companies would have exceeded Rs. 70,000 crores in the current fiscal
year. Since this is unsustainable, it is argued, the hike in prices
and a shift out of a controlled pricing regime is unavoidable.
The government's argument is by no means water-tight. While under-recoveries
are a reality, they do not turn oil refining and marketing firms into
loss-making enterprises, because those firms deliver a range of products
and services, the prices of all of which are not controlled. If, for
example, even if we consider the profit after taxes of the most important
oil companies over the last ten years, they have remained positive in
all years and quite substantially so in some. Under-recoveries are notional
losses that only lower book profits relative to some benchmark. Thus,
there is little danger that the industry would be bankrupted even if
prices were kept at their earlier levels.
There is, of course, the question of fairness. Since there are many
players involved in the industry there is no reason why under-recoveries
should affect only the books of the oil marketing companies. The returns
on net worth earned by the oil marketing companies are far more volatile
and vulnerable than that garnered by the upstream oil companies (ONGC,
OIL and GAIL). The burden should be shared by the latter, which receive
prices that more than compensate for costs; by the central government
which garners revenues in the form of customs duties and excise duties
(besides dividends from the oil majors); and by the state governments
which benefit from sales taxes. This requires, for example, the oil
refineries to offer discounts when selling products to the OMCs and
for the government to reduce the taxes it levies on oil products in
order to absorb part of the under-recovery.
The controversial question as to how the burden should be shared was
analysed by a committee headed by C. Rangarajan appointed to examine
the issue. The committee spent much of its energies on the different
stages through which imported and domestic crude is converted into petroleum
products supplied to the consumer, and the cost escalation that arises
as the raw material passes through these stages. The numbers suggested
that there was an adequate buffer to shield domestic consumers from
the effects of increases in international prices, so long as segments
that can afford to take a cut in petroleum-related revenues because
they have alternative sources of resource mobilisation are willing to
accept such a reduction.
Thus, if at all there is an argument for price deregulation it can only
be that it is for some reason wrong to expect the oil companies and
the government to bear the burden of the irrational fluctuations in
the global prices of oil. That argument too is difficult to justify.
When the industry was wholly in the public sector, the prices of oil
products were treated as one set of instruments in the tax-cum-subsidy
regime of the government. Any losses suffered by the industry or any
shortfall in funds required for investment as a result of price regulation
were to be met from resources mobilised through progressive taxes rather
than from regressive price increases. The government should have adopted
a similar approach in the current situation and focused on rules that
can and have been devised.
It needs to be noted here that oil prices have not been held constant
in recent history. Rather the average annual increase in prices over
the last two decades indicate that the increase has been much higher
in the case of retail prices of petrol, for example, than in the wholesale
price index for all commodities. The common person has indeed borne
some of the burden of volatile oil prices.
The question remains as to why the government is adopting policies that
transfer most of the burden onto the aam aadmi and aggravate
inflation. Ideological commitment to neoliberal policies and misplaced
belief in their ability to put India on the ''world stage'' may be playing
a role. But, more importantly, the government's moves or lack of them
seem intended to favour corporate interests of various kinds. Hopefully,
the opposition would be able to drive home the point that the people
are not willing to accept this kind of cynical extraction of surpluses
for profit.